What Is a Market?
A market is a place where parties can gather to facilitate the exchange of goods and services. The parties involved are usually buyers and sellers. The market may be physical like a retail outlet, where people meet face-to-face, or virtual like an online market, where there is no direct physical contact between buyers and sellers. There are some key characteristics that help define a market, including the availability of an arena, buyers and sellers, and a commodity that can be purchased and sold.
Key Takeaways
- A market is a place where buyers and sellers can meet to facilitate the exchange or transaction of goods and services.
- Markets can be physical like a retail outlet, or virtual like an e-retailer.
- Other examples include illegal markets, auction markets, and financial markets.
- Markets establish the prices of goods and services that are determined by supply and demand.
- Features of a market include the availability of an arena, buyers and sellers, and a commodity.
Market
Understanding Markets
A market is any place where two or more parties can meet to engage in an economic transaction—even those that don’t involve legal tender. A market transaction may involve goods, services, information, currency, or any combination of these that pass from one party to another. In short, markets are arenas in which buyers and sellers can gather and interact.
Two parties are generally needed to make a trade. But, at minimum, a third party is required to introduce competition and bring balance to the market. As such, a market in a state of perfect competition, among other things, is characterized by a high number of active buyers and sellers.
Beyond this broad definition, the term market encompasses a variety of things, depending on the context. For instance, it may refer to the stock market, which is the place where securities are traded. It may also be used to describe a collection of people who wish to buy a specific product or service in a specific place, such as the Brooklyn housing market. Or it could refer to an industry or business sector, such as the global diamond market.
Certain decisions that help shape the market are determined by an economic system known as the market economy. In this system, factors like investments and the production, distribution, and pricing of goods and services are led by supply and demand from businesses and individuals. As such, a market economy is unplanned and is not part of a planned or command economy where the government dictates all of these factors. Examples of market economies include the United States, Canada, the United Kingdom, and Japan.
In the United States, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) regulates the stock, bond, and currency markets. It puts provisions in place to prevent fraud while ensuring traders and investors have the right information to make the most informed decisions possible.
Supply and Demand
Whatever the context, a market establishes the prices for goods and other services. These rates are determined by supply and demand. The idea of supply and demand is one of the very basics of economics. Supply is created by the sellers, while demand is generated by buyers.
Markets try to find some balance in price when supply and demand are themselves in balance. But that balance can in itself be disrupted by factors other than price including incomes, expectations, technology, the cost of production, and the number of buyers and sellers participating.
To put it simply, the number of goods and services available is determined by what people want and how eager they are to buy. Sellers increase production when buyers demand more goods and services. Producers then increase their prices in order to realize a profit. When buyer demand decreases, companies have to drop their prices and, therefore, the number of goods and services they bring to market.
Physical and Virtual Markets
Markets may be represented by physical locations where transactions are made. These include retail stores and other similar businesses that sell individual items to wholesale markets selling goods to distributors. Or they may be virtual. Internet-based stores and auction sites such as Amazon and eBay are examples of markets where transactions can take place entirely online and the parties involved never connect physically.
Markets may emerge organically or as a means of enabling ownership rights over goods, services, and information. When on a national or other more specific regional level, markets may often be categorized as developed or developing markets. This distinction depends on many factors, including income levels and the nation or region’s openness to foreign trade.
The size of a market is determined by the number of buyers and sellers, as well as the amount of money that changes hands each year.
Types of Markets
Markets vary widely for a number of reasons, including the kinds of products sold, location, duration, size, and constituency of the customer base, size, legality, and many other factors. Aside from the two most common markets—physical and virtual—there are other kinds of markets where parties can gather to execute their transactions.
Underground Market
An underground or black market refers to an illegal market where transactions occur without the knowledge of the government or other regulatory agencies. Many illegal markets exist in order to circumvent existing tax laws. This is why many involve cash-only transactions or non-traceable forms of currency, making them harder to track.
Many illegal markets exist in countries that are economically developing and with planned or command economies where the government controls the production and distribution of goods and services. When there is a shortage of certain goods and services in the economy, members of the illegal market step in and fill the void.
Illegal markets can also exist in developed economies. These shadow markets, as they’re also known, become prevalent when prices control the sale of certain products or services, especially when demand is high. Ticket scalping is one example of an illegal or shadow market. When demand for concert or theater tickets is high, scalpers will step in, buy up a bunch, and sell them at inflated prices on the underground market.
Auction Market
An auction market brings many people together for the sale and purchase of specific lots of goods. The buyers or bidders try to top each other for the purchase price. The items up for sale end up going to the highest bidder.
The most common auction markets involve livestock, foreclosed homes, and art and antiques. Many operate online now. For example, the U.S. Treasury sells its bonds, notes, and bills via regular auctions.
Financial Market
The blanket term financial market refers to any place where securities, currencies, bonds, and other securities are traded between two parties. These markets are the basis of capitalist societies, and they provide capital formation and liquidity for businesses. They can be physical or virtual.
The financial market includes the stock exchanges such as the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), Nasdaq, the London Stock Exchange (LSE), and the TMX Group. Other kinds of financial markets include the bond market and the foreign exchange market, where people trade currencies.
Features of a Market
There are certain features that help define a market. These are necessary in order for the market to function. The following are the most basic characteristics that shape a market:
- Arena: This is the platform where transactions are conducted between buyers and sellers. Keep in mind that this doesn’t necessarily mean a physical location. It can also mean the area in which all parties involved are spread out.
- Buyers and Sellers: In order for the market to function, there must be buyers and there must be sellers. The market can’t exist if someone isn’t buying something that someone else is selling. These entities can be businesses, individuals, or even governments, and they can execute their transactions physically or virtually, thanks to the internet.
- One Commodity: A single market is dependent on a single commodity, so in order for a market to operate, a related commodity must be present. For instance, wheat is the commodity bought and sold in the wheat market. Electronics make up the electronics market en masse but can be broken down into subcategories.
There are other features, including competition, pricing, and the freedom to buy and sell goods and services.
Regulating Markets
Other than underground markets, most markets are subject to rules and regulations set by a regional or governing body that determines the market’s nature. This may be the case when the regulation is as wide-reaching and as widely recognized as an international trade agreement, or as local and temporary as a pop-up street market where vendors maintain order and rules among themselves.
How Do Markets Work?
Markets are arenas in which buyers and sellers can gather and interact. A market in a state of perfect competition is necessarily characterized by a high number of active buyers and sellers. The market establishes the prices for goods and other services. These rates are determined by supply and demand. Supply is created by the sellers, while demand is generated by buyers. Markets try to find some balance in price when supply and demand are themselves in balance.
What Is a Black Market?
A black market refers to an illegal exchange or marketplace where transactions occur without the knowledge or oversight of officials or regulatory agencies. They tend to spring up when there is a shortage of certain goods and services in the economy, or supply and prices are state-controlled. Transactions tend to be undocumented and cash-only, all the better to be untraceable.
How Are Markets Regulated?
Most markets are subject to rules and regulations set by a regional or governing body that determines the market’s nature. They can be international, national, or local authorities.
The Bottom Line
Markets are an important part of the economy. They allow a space where governments, businesses, and individuals can buy and sell their goods and services. But that’s not all. They help determine the pricing of goods and services and inject much-needed liquidity into the economy. By offering a place to conduct transactions, markets allow entities access to the capital they need to further their interests, whether that’s to fund infrastructure, fulfill growth plans, make purchases, or invest their money. This helps fuel innovation in order to secure a competitive edge in the marketplace.
Market
The term ‘market’ refers to the aggregate of all demand for a particular product or service, arising from the aggregate of all consumers, both existing and potential for the product. It means that the whole group of consumers of a particular product constitutes the ‘market’ for that product.
Philip Kotler states, “A market consists of all the potential customers sharing a particular need or wants who might be willing and able to engage in exchange to satisfy that need or want.”
Learn about:-
1. Definitions of Market 2. Meaning of Market 3. Concept 4. Characteristics 5. Importance 6. Evolution 7. Market Research 8. Market Structure 9. Types of Consumer Market 10. Methods for Estimating Area Market Demand 11. Entities 12. Benefits 13. Market Survey.
Market: Definitions, Meaning, Concept, Characteristics, Importance, Evolution, Types, Methods, Advantages and Benefits
Market – Definitions
A definition of the market is based on building on up-to-date picture of the parameters of the market. Its size, composition, consumption patterns and internal structure. This needs to be done regularly, as changes can occur rapidly with little apparent warning. The ability to define the market as tightly and accurately as possible is the measure of marketing staff who are on top of their jobs.
Many companies have the practice of maintaining a “Marketing Fact Book” for each product and brand area in which they have an interest. In Industrial markets problems can be caused by the difficulties faced when attempting to define the markets in categories such as components or processed products.
The greater the firm’s awareness of a market, the more management will become conscious of the different groups which make it up. This process of breaking up large heterogeneous groups into more homogeneous target audiences is central to the marketing process. A market is thus by definition comprises interest, purchasing power and willingness to service that satisfies a need.
Market segmentation is a method of dividing a large market into smaller groupings of consumers or organisations in which each segment has a common characteristic such as needs or behaviour.
Essentially a market could be considered to be a meeting place for making exchanges, where it is accepted that the relative value of different products is established. In practice, to be effective a market needs to have rules and procedures for their enforcement. This is the basis for the definition used by economists.
The word market is also often used to mean the individuals or organisations who are or could be purchasers of a particular product. Very often this can cause confusion. For instance, the UK car market could mean the 12 million existing car users, or more usually the 1.5 million or so new cars which are purchased in any one year. It is important always to use the word carefully so that its meaning is clear, and to ensure that you understand how it is being used when you come across it in your reading.
Market is a place where buyers and sellers meet. In other words we can say ‘Market’ means a group of sellers.
However, Traditionally the term ‘market’ has been used to describe a place where buyers and sellers gather to exchange goods and services, e.g., a fruit and vegetable market or a stock market.
In marketing, the term market refers to the group of consumers or organisations that is interested in the product, has the resource to purchase the product, and is permitted by law and other regulations to acquire the product.
Cournot, defines the ‘Market’ as “Economists understand by the term market, not any particular market place in which things are bought and sold, but the whole of any region in which buyers and sellers are in such free intercourse with one another that the prices of the same goods tend to be at equality easily and quickly.”
Philip Kotler states, “A market consists of all the potential customers sharing a particular need or wants who might be willing and able to engage in exchange to satisfy that need or want.”
So the size of the market depends upon the number of persons who have the unsatisfied needs and are potentially capable of performing the exchange.
A market (in contrast to marketing) may be defined as:
“The actual or potential buyers of a product”.
This means that a market is wider than individuals and it includes private and public sector organisations, supplier groups and purchasing groups. It is also wider than present or past buyers. It includes anyone or any organisation that is reasonably likely to buy a product in the future.
Kotler (1986) defined a product broadly as:
“… anything that can be offered to a market for attention, acquisition, use or consumption that might satisfy a want or need. It includes physical objects, services, persons, places, organisations and ideas”.
An organisation that hopes to sell its product in a market needs to study the market very carefully and may commission extensive market research.
It will need to examine the characteristics of the market such as:
(a) The people and organisations that make up the market
(b) The product that it is bought
(c) The purpose for which it will be bought and the needs it will satisfy
(d) The times and occasions (e.g. birthdays, setting up a new home or everyday purchases) when the product is bought
(e) The method used to buy the product (e.g. visit to retail outlet, regular order, telephone order or Internet shopping)
It should be remembered that people and organisations do not buy products for their own sake. Products are bought because they solve a problem or confer benefits upon their owners. For example, organisations do not purchase a car for a sales representative because it is a good thing in itself.
The car will be purchased because the organisation believes it will benefit from the sales representative’s ability to visit more customers each day and because it can be sure that its image will not be damaged by the representative arriving at customers premises driving a clapped-out banger.
Markets can differ in many ways. The main differences are size, competition, barriers and dynamism.
Market – Meaning
Traditionally, market refers to a physical location where buyers and sellers gather to exchange their goods. In the market, ownership and possession of products is transferred from the seller to the buyer and money acts as a medium of exchange and measure of value. Economists describe a market as a collection of buyers and sellers who transact over a particular product or service.
Marketers view sellers as the industry and buyers as the market. Business people use the term market to refer to various grouping of customers, i.e., Product market (Example- Television market), Geographic market (Example- African market) or Non- customer group such as labour market. Market also refers to the aggregate demand of the potential buyers for a product or service.
In this sense market means people with needs to satisfy, the money to spend and the will to spend money to satisfy their needs. Therefore the term “Market” has a wider meaning and it is not confined to a particular physical place. It is an area in which forces of demand and supply operate directly or by means of any kind of communication to bring about transfer in the title of the goods.
Marketing is an activity involving movement of goods and its basis as is market. Hence it will be helpful for the study of marketing, to understand origin of the word ‘Market’.
The word “Market” is derived from the Latin word ‘Marcatus’ meaning gathering for the purpose of commerce, fair.
Some scholars state that the word ‘Market’ is derived from the Latin word ‘Marcari’ or ‘Merx’ meaning trade, buy or merchandise goods. Latin notion basically dealt with buying or selling of goods.
Thus marketing refers to trading of goods through the process of buying and selling. And market is a place of business where marketing activities are organized. And therefore market contains present and prospective customers for a particular product or service.
Market – Concept
The term market has several meanings. It can be used in the sense of the network of institutions like wholesalers, dealers etc. dealing in the product. It can also be used to refer to the nature of demand for the product, as when we speak of the market for toothpaste. However, it must be remembered that the above two meanings of market are related yet distinct, so a change in one does not necessitate a change in the other.
Usually, market is used to identify competition and to break down the market into segments. If viewed this way, the ‘market for’ mill be referred to in relation to the function (s) served by the product. Products having the same utility and performing the same function will be competing with each other and hence in the same market. A firm’s business is defined in terms of technology, customer group and function(s) served. So it would be more appropriate to refer to (or define) market in terms of its function (or purpose) served, which in turn will coincide with the customer group it is to serve.
Going by the above description on the term ‘market’, it can be inferred that buyers in the same market seek products for broadly the same function. But buyers hold different beliefs on what their interpretation is about that product which performs the functions efficiently. As a result, they are aware of the various brand options and will be attracted to different offerings based on how the brand will cater more closely to their wants.
Market – 4 Main Characteristics
1. It shall be wide enough so that there is existence of a steady and continuous demand for the commodity under sale. If there is no steady demand there cannot be steady and continuous sale. If there is no steady demand there cannot be steady and continuous supply of the commodity. The suppliers can hold the stock when there is excess supply to adjust it with the demand.
2. There shall be facilities for movement of the goods so that the supply of a commodity may reach the market easily, regularly and timely.
3. The commodity must be capable of being identified and preferably be represented by sample or by description.
4. The title to or ownership of goods must pass easily from the seller to the buyer with minimum formalities.
5. There shall be freedom of entering into contracts by the buyers and the sellers among themselves for executing transactions of sale.
Market – Importance
1. Reciprocal Benefits – The buyers can get their goods for the satisfaction of their wants and the sellers also get their market for their merchandising operations.
2. Incentive to Producers – The goods are produced for marketing, i.e., selling to the consumers. In the absence of any market, the goods cannot be sold. The existence of a market provides incentive to the manufacturers to produce the goods.
3. Generation of Employment – The activities of repeated buying and selling of goods and services in a market call for the services to be rendered by different people. This way, a market creates opportunities of employment to people in various capacities like dealers and agents, etc.
4. Index of Economic Situation – The economic condition of a country can be gauged by the presence of a market. A country possessing an international or global market for its products and/or services is considered as an economically advanced one in the world of business.
5. Supply vs. Demand Adjustment – The existence of a market creates demand for goods and services. Certain raw materials like cotton, jute, etc. have seasonal supplies but their demands are regular and continuous. An organized market for them ensures adjustments between the demand and supplies and stabilization of prices over a long period.
Market – Evolution
Market as described by Latin word marcatus involved gathering of people with various commodities and goods or even services for sale. In the early stages trade was made with only Barter System involving exchange of goods in return of other goods on the basis of some common equality of value.
After the invention of money in business, the use of Barter System was discontinued from the market and more stabilized form of value exchange was introduced which helped trade and commerce to run smoothly. In today’s dynamic and rapidly developing environment market is a whole country or may be the whole world and it consists of people who are rapidly connected with each other for trading and business activities.
Financial transactions are also possible via internet, throughout the world. One can easily access whole market for purchasing single commodity and can very easily buy that particular product through e-commerce, online market. Payment options have also become very virtual.
Thus market is developed from busy streets and people with goods, who are waiting for buyer for purchase to a totally different scenario of virtual setup and across the globe with buyer and seller who are totally unknown to each other making business of buying and selling. Hence study is to be made covering this special aspect of technological advancement its effect on market conditions and even on traditional definition of market.
Market Research
Marketing decisions require a lot of information. The process of collecting and collating this information in a systematic and objective away is called market research.
It is defined by the American Marketing Association as:
“… The function that links the consumer, customer and public to the marketer through information – information used to identify and define marketing opportunities and problems; generate, refine and evaluate marketing actions; monitor marketing performance; and improve understanding of marketing as a process”.
The terms “market research”, “markets research” and “marketing research” sound very similar and are often used interchangeably. Technically, however, market research refers to any information about markets. Markets research is a part of market research and looks at the characteristics of markets. Marketing research deals with information relevant to marketing a specific product or service. To avoid confusion it is therefore helpful to divide market research into two main categories: markets research and marketing research.
Markets Research:
Research on markets is sometimes called “market intelligence”. It obtains information, usually quantitative, on many of the market characteristics such as the size of a market, growth, use of technology, dynamism and level of competition. Often markets research is based on existing (secondary) data compiled by government and industry sources such as census figures, the retail price index and the value of certain imported goods. It may also use journal and newspaper articles to build up a picture of competitors.
Marketing Research:
Marketing research focuses upon the information that will be useful to organisations who wish to sell specific products. It is the research which, say, the brand manager for Coca-Cola would use to devise a campaign to increase Coca-Cola’s market share. While marketing research has some overlap with research on markets, its focus is narrower and it is closer to the actual point of sale. Marketing research can, perhaps, the best considered under two headings- its uses and its methods.
Uses of Marketing Research:
Marketing research can play a vital role in bringing to market a product that is valued by customers and which is presented to them in an enjoyable way.
Marketing research’s main uses include:
(a) Product generation – marketing research can be used to identify new products. These ideas can be obtained by listening to consumers or by holding brainstorming sessions with designers and marketing executives.
(b) Product improvement and embellishment – existing products can be improved or made more attractive. Again, the source of suggestions can be obtained from consumers or brainstorming sessions. Ideas may also be generated by examining competitors’ products or even products and services in other markets.
(c) Product testing and refinement – prototypes of products and services can be tested on small groups of consumers. Their reactions and comments are usually incorporated in a modified product.
(d) Consumer targeting – marketing research can help pinpoint the people who are most likely to buy the product or use a service.
(e) Sales forecasting.
(f) Packaging and advertising design – various suggestions for packaging can be tested out on samples of consumers and the most effective packages or adverts chosen.
(g) Point-of-sale displays and procedures – marketing research can be used to develop and then refine point of sale displays, brochures and other factors that might influence the experience of a buyer.
Market – Structure (With Classification and Types)
A market refers to a suitable arrangement in which the buyers and sellers could closely interact (physically or otherwise) to arrive at exchange decisions. The demand and supply forces meet in the market to allocate resources. On one hand, firms compete for the scarce resources in order to produce and on the other, consumers compete in the market for their demands.
Market structure refers to the relationship between buyers and sellers, the forms of competition among the firms in the same industry, and the special features of a market in affecting the demand and supply forces. Markets are classified, broadly, depending upon the importance of an individual firm in relation to the entire market and whether products placed in the market are homogenous or not.
Using these two broad criteria, markets are classified into four broad categories—pure competition, pure monopoly, oligopoly, and monopolistic competition. In reality, markets may not fit into any one of these categories; they may be a mixture of two or more types of markets or it may have characteristics close to one of these categories.
However, an understanding of the broad classifications of markets provides a framework for analysing the demand curve faced by a firm or a business entity.
Classification # 1. Pure Competition:
In this market model there are a large number of firms having a homogenous or standardized product. Firms can enter or exit easily and have perfect knowledge about the markets.
In brief, the important characteristics of such a market are:
i. Very large numbers of buyers and sellers;
ii. Standardized product similar in all respects being produced by each firm;
iii. ‘Price takers’—firms accept the price as given;
iv. Free entry and exit for sellers; and
v. Perfect knowledge about the market.
Thus, if one or few firms quit the market, supply does not decrease enough to cause a change in the market price as no seller is big enough to influence it. The market price is determined by the forces of demand and supply operating in the market. Buyers and sellers have to accept the market price as given and are called price-takers.
They have complete information about the price, quality, and quantity sold in the market. As a result, there is no role for advertisement in such a market condition. Agricultural markets for wheat, sugar, rice; grocery stores of similar size; restaurants, etc. are examples of markets operating in pure competition.
Demand Curve:
The demand curve faced by sellers is horizontal at the prevailing equilibrium price. It is said to be perfectly elastic, that is, at the given price, sellers can sell all that they have to offer. However, at any price above the market equilibrium price, firms would not be in a position to sell any quantity. They can sell all they want to sell at the going market price.
In case of a firm operating under pure competition, it has to adjust itself to the market prices as given. If market supply increases resulting in a decrease in the price to P1, the demand curve faced by the firm would shift downward to d1d1 (Fig. 10.2). The firm has to just adjust itself to the given reduced price and adjust its output accordingly.
Normal Profit:
A perfectly competitive industry would be in equilibrium when each and every individual firm in the industry is in equilibrium, that is, each firm maximizes its profit by equating marginal revenue with marginal cost and the industry, as a whole, is in equilibrium. It means that no firm enters or leaves the market.
This happens when every entrepreneur in the industry earns normal profit—gains that are sufficient to sustain the seller in the industry. Thus, if in the industry, profits of all entrepreneurs rise above ‘normal’, then new firms will be encouraged to enter the industry leading to an extra supply and reduction in the prices.
This will lead to a new equilibrium price at which, again, every entrepreneur will just earn normal profits. Similarly, in case profits for everyone fall below ‘normal’, some firms will quit the market, decreasing supply, leading to an increase in prices. This will set a new equilibrium price at which all entrepreneurs will just earn normal profits.
Classification # 2. Pure Monopoly:
Pure monopoly operates in a market when a single firm is the sole producer of a product for which there are no close substitutes. There are no similar products in the market whose prices or sales can influence, the monopolist’s price or sales substantially and vice versa.
Thus, cross elasticity of demand for the monopolist’s product is either zero or negligible. Neither does he expect a reaction from other firms nor do the actions of other firms in the market affect them. A monopolist is the only industry for the product that he produces. He may or may not engage in non-price competition.
Depending on the nature of its product, a monopolist may advertise to increase demand. However, he may not indulge in aggressive marketing, as he faces no competitors in the market. There are a number of products where the producers have a substantial amount of monopoly power and are called ‘near’ monopolies.
Examples of pure monopolies are public utilities such as gas, electricity, water, and railways. Western Union’s money transfer facility and the De Beers’s diamond syndicate are examples of ‘near’ monopolies. Monopolies can also be geographic in nature; for example, a small town may have only one bank branch or a single bus service.
Barriers to Entry:
Economies of scale have one major barrier—in case a production requires a massive investment and a large firm with a large market share already exists, new firms cannot afford to start industries with economies of scale. Public utilities have natural monopolies as they have economies of scale; where one firm is the most efficient in satisfying existing demand.
The government usually gives one firm the right to operate a public utility industry in exchange for government regulation of its power. Further, there can be legal barriers for entry in the form of patents and licenses.
Demand Curve:
The market demand curve would be a demand curve for the monopolist (Fig. 10.3). Since he is the only seller of the product in the market, he can sell exactly the quantity that buyers would buy at a given price.
Being alone in the market, a monopolist is able to exert some amount of influence on the price, output, and demand for the product. A monopolist can increase sales by lowering the price and restrict them by increasing the price, according to market demand. It can change its demand curve by using promotional tactics such as selective price-cutting and advertising.
A monopolist can effectively operate on price discrimination strategies that is charging different prices from different buyers for the same product, provided it can segregate the market by dividing the buyers into separate categories according to their ability or willingness to pay for the product (usually based on differing elasticities of demand).
The basic condition for effectively operating on price discrimination strategy is that buyers must be unable to resell the original product or service to derive price advantage.
Examples of effective price discrimination are airline companies charging high fares from executive travellers (inelastic demand) than vacation travellers (elastic demand); power companies that frequently segment their markets according to their end uses, such as lighting and heating, commercial users, and agriculture purposes (lack of substitutes for lighting makes this demand inelastic).
Classification # 3. Oligopoly:
In an oligopoly market situation, there are few sellers and the decision of one affects the other because of the sellers’ small size. Thus, changes in the output and price of one firm affect the price and the quantities that another firm would be able to sell in the market. Individual sellers in an oligopoly market are interdependent and not independent.
Each of the players in the market has to be very receptive to its competitor’s actions. Their goods may be homogeneous or heterogeneous. There are some barriers for entry into this industry arising on account of patents, high set-up cost, or specialized technology.
As a result, knowledge and information about each other’s operations is imperfect. Sellers in an oligopoly market usually turn to advertising to improve their sales. Some examples of oligopolies are banks, automotive manufacturers, gas companies, insurance companies, telecommunications companies, etc.
Oligopoly markets are normally classified into two broad categories—pure oligopoly and differentiated oligopoly. In a pure oligopoly market, firms produce homogeneous products while in a differentiated oligopoly market, firms produce and sell differentiated products.
Although these products are close substitutes to each other and have a high cross elasticity of demand, each firm’s product has its own unique characteristics to distinguish it from the other in terms of quality, design, packaging, size, etc. A market structure characterized by two producers is a specialized form of oligopoly, referred to as duopoly.
Demand Curve:
The interdependence of sellers in an oligopoly market makes it difficult to estimate the demand for each firm. The demand for a firm’s products cannot be determined if the firm is unable to predict the reactions of its competitors to changes in its price and output decisions.
However, if the firm can predict the reaction of its competitors with some accuracy, the demand curve for the firm can be estimated and would be correspondingly more determinate.
An oligopolistic firm is in a position to influence its demand curve to some extent and, consequentially, its price and output. An oligopolist can shift its demand curve upwards with the help of advertising and other promotional efforts to induce consumers to disassociate from its rivals and switch to its brand.
However, the firm’s rivals would also be ready with their moves to counter it. Ultimately, firms that succeed in their strategies of advertising campaign or other promotional measures would succeed in increasing the demand for their brands. Whether the firm faces a determinate or an indeterminate demand curve, it knows when it faces a downward sloping demand curve.
It can increase its sales by reduction in the price of the product, unless the objective is achieved through upward shift in the demand curve. Generally, the elasticity of demand faced by an oligopolist would be elastic because of the availability of good substitutes. However, elasticity of demand depends on the rival’s reactions to the price and output changes of the single seller.
Classification # 4. Monopolistic Competition:
Monopolistic competition is a market situation wherein there are many sellers of a particular product that are differentiated in some way or the other. Like those in a pure competitive market, each seller is too small to influence the decision of the other. The relationship between different sellers is impersonal.
The products get differentiated by brand name, quality, trademarks, post-sale service, packaging, etc. The cross elasticities of demand are high as though differentiated, and the products are good substitutes of each other. Enterprises that fall under monopolistic competition include beauty clinics, hosiery items, service trades, textile products, etc.
For example, there are many beauty clinics in the country and a majority of them are small. The entry is free and people know enough about their hairdressing options, that is, ‘sufficient knowledge’ is available to the buyers. However, the products of different beauty clinics are differentiated in some way or other and, therefore, are not perfect substitutes.
The difference between monopolistic competition and perfect competition is that in monopolistic competition, production does not take place at the lowest possible cost. Due to this, firms are left with excess production capacity. Chamberlin (1946) and Robinson (1933) developed this market concept.
Demand Curve:
The demand curve faced by the firm has typical basis because of differentiation of products. The demand faced by a firm in a pure competition, wherein products are homogenous, is perfectly elastic. The differentiation makes the consumers attached to the brand and, therefore, the demand curve becomes somewhat elastic from perfectly elastic.
It implies that consumers would continue to purchase a product from a particular firm even if there is some degree of variation in the price, but beyond a point they would switchover to another product which is a close substitute. Thus, a firm operating in the monopolistic competition attempts to have a relatively less elastic demand by differentiating its products and creating a niche for its products in the market.
In monopolistic competition, firms may enjoy economic gains, that is, profits over and above normal profits. However, because of free entry (as in pure competition), economic profits will be zero in the long run. As long as there are positive economic profits, there will be new entrants into the industry leading to a squeeze in the economic profits.
Therefore, positive economic profits will not be stable in a monopolistically competitive industry. However, some economists believe that a monopolistically competitive industry may have high prices because non-price competition raises costs.
The individual firms in monopolistic competitive markets may be in a position to influence the demand and price of its product to some degree through advertising. However, their influence is limited because of availability of good substitutes in the market.
Although a firm in a monopolistic competitive market faces a situation similar to that of a firm in a perfectly competitive market, it operates to some extent like a monopoly, as it has some control over its prices and output. However, if a firm raises the prices of its products beyond a certain tolerable limit, it loses all its customers.
At the same time, it does not have to bring its prices too low to secure all the customers it can handle. So, outside a given price range, the firm operates under the forces of pure competition.
Types of Market Structure
A market consists of groups of buyers and sellers. The most common feature among all buyers and all sellers is that they are very different. Though they share some common characteristics they can be divided into some distinct groups, which are different among themselves in terms of nature and size of market, nature and size of purchase, purpose of purchase, etc. We can study four different types of Markets.
They are:
1. Consumer market,
2. Business market,
3. Government market,
4. Institutional market.
Type # 1. Consumer Markets:
It is a very wide market. It consists of the all the people who have some unsatisfied demand. The number of buyers is large in number. But since the purchases done by them are for the personal consumption and not to utilize it for selling or further production, individuals buy in small quantities. Because of the large number of consumers there is no close relationship between them and the manufacturer. Along with the large numbers the buyers as widely distributed also.
The entire world is consumer market. As there is large number of buyers and as these buyers are geographically widespread, there are a large number of middlemen the distribution channel. The purchase is small in quantity and the consumers have many alternatives to choose from. So they are very sensitive to price change. The demand in the consumer market is price elastic.
Type # 2. Business Markets:
The business market consists of all the organizations that acquire goods and services used in the production of other products or services that are sold, rented, or supplied to others. Thus, the business market do not purchase for personal consumption.
These can be of two types:
(i) Industrial Markets:
Here, the major criterion is keeping production satisfied in order to that materials and components are available for incorporation in production process. The ultimate objective is to satisfy the needs of the company’s customers, be they intermediate manufacturers further down the production chain or end customers.
(ii) Resale Markets:
This is the case where the principal criterion is the mark-up percentage that can be added to goods that are purchased from manufacturers and wholesalers in bulk and then resold to individual customers.
Type # 3. Government Markets:
In most countries, government organizations are a major buyer of goods and services. Especially in the developing country like India, where the major infrastructural projects and production are government undertakings, government markets become a very important part. The government unit will make allowance for suppliers’ superior quality or reputation for completing contracts on time.
They tend to favor domestic suppliers over foreign suppliers. Government organizations require considerable paper work from suppliers. Hence there is a delay in decision-making due to excessive paper work and bureaucracy. There are too many regulations to be followed. There is red- tapism in government market. They, purchase in large quantities. Cost or price plays a very major role. Product differentiation advertising and personal selling have less consequence in winning bids.
Type # 4. Institutional Markets:
Institutional market consists of schools, hospitals, nursing homes, prisons and other institutions that must provide goods and services to people in their care. Many of these organizations are characterized by low budgets and captive clienteles.
For example, hospitals have to decide what quality of food to buy the patients. The buying objective here is not profit, because the food is provided to the patients as part of the total service package; nor is cost minimization the sale objective because poor food will cause patients to complain and hurt the hospital s reputation.
The hospital’s purchasing agent has to search for institutional food vendors whose quality meets or exceeds a certain minimum standard and whose prices are low. In fact, many food vendors set up separate division to sell to institutional buyers.
Similarly in case of a bank the stationeries for the forms and dockets are purchased not with a profit motive but as a part of the service package offered.
Market – 4 Main Types of Consumer Market
Consumer markets are the markets for products and services like Car, LED TV, Refrigerators, Toothpaste, Ice Cream, Apparels, Air travel etc., bought by individuals for their own or family use. In the consumer market, companies try to identify and meet the needs of the consumer through their product and service offering.
Additionally, they try to position the products into the consumers mind for better awareness and purchases.
Consumer markets can be classified in the following way:
1. Fast Moving Consumer Goods (FMCG):
Fast Moving Consumer Goods widely known as FMCG, generally include a wide variety of frequently purchased products such as toothpaste, shampoo, soap, cosmetics, hair oil and detergents, as well as other non- durables such as plastic goods, CFL bulbs, paper & stationery and glassware. FMCG may also include chocolates, pharmaceuticals, packaged food products and soft drinks.
These goods are of low unit value with high volume potential and require frequent repurchase. In 2013, the market size was Rs. 2.2 lakh-crore in India. The top 10 companies in the FMCG sector are Hindustan Unilever Limited (HUL), ITC, Nestle India, Amul, Dabur, Asian Paints, Cadbury India, Britannia Industries, Procter & Gamble and Marico Industries. Other leading companies in this segment are Reckitt Benckiser, GlaxoSmithKline, Pepsi, Coke, Himalaya, Bajaj, Godrej etc.
Now there is a new subset of FMCG called Fast Moving Consumer Electronics (FMCE), which include innovative electronic products like MP3 players, mobile phones and digital cameras. These are replaced more frequently than other electronic products.
2. Consumer Durables:
On the contrary, Consumer durables are low volume products with high per unit value. It is also known as White Goods or Brown Goods. White goods include Refrigerators, Freezers, Washing Machines, Dishwashers, and Microwaves etc; while Brown goods include TVs, DVD players, Home Theatres, Camcorders, Game consoles like Microsoft ZBox 360, Sony Playstation, Nintendo WI, personal computers etc.
When the goods are not classified as White goods or brown goods, then it is called white goods on the whole, which also includes household electronics items, earlier categorised under brown goods.
3. Soft Goods:
Soft goods are relatively priced higher than the FMCGs and lesser than the consumer durables. These goods are also low volume in nature, as it requires a shorter replacement cycle. For examples – Clothing Material, Apparels, Shoes etc.
4. Yellow Goods:
Besides white and brown goods, there is another not so popular classification of Yellow Goods. Yellow Goods include material for construction and earth moving equipment, fork lift trucks and quarrying equipment. The term is also used for agricultural equipment like tractors.
Services:
Beside the goods, consumer markets also require a lot of services. Goods are physical, tangible articles, while Services are nonphysical and intangible in nature. Services can also satisfy a need like goods. Financial services, Banking, Telecom, DTH, Courier, Hotel, Airline, Multiplex, Train, Doctors, Lawyers, Healthcare and Management Consultancy are all examples of services.
Services require an additional set of marketing mix tools than the goods market like people, process and physical evidence, besides the 4Ps – product, price, place and promotion.
Market – 2 Important Methods for Estimating Area Market Demand
1. Market Build-Up Method:
The market build-up method requires identifying all the potential buyers in each market and estimating their potential purchases. Suppose a manufacturer of mining instruments invented an instrument for assessing the gold content in gold-bearing ores. The instrument can be used in the field to test gold ore. With the help of it miners would not waste their time digging deposits of ore containing too little gold to be commercially profitable.
Each mine would buy one or more such instrument depending on the mine’s size. The company wants to determine the market potential for this instrument in each mining area and whether to hire a sales person to cover that area. The company would place a salesperson in each area that has a market potential of Rs.5,00,000.
2. Market Factor-Index Method:
Consumer goods companies have to estimate area market potentials starting with Calcutta market. Think of a manufacturer of T-shirts who wishes to evaluate its sales performance relative to market potential in several major market areas. It has estimated total national potential for T-shirts at Rs. 1 crore per year.
The company’s current nationwide sales are about 10% of the total potential market. The company wants to know whether its share of Calcutta market is higher or lower than 10% of market share. To find out this the company has to calculate the market potential in the Calcutta market.
A common method for calculating area market potential is to identify market factors that correlate with market potential and combine them into a weighted index. An example of this method is called the buying power index. The buying power index is based on three factors —the areas of the nation’s disposable personal income, retail sales and population.
Estimating Actual Sales and Market Shares:
Besides estimating total and area demand a company has to know the actual industry sales in its market. Thus it must identify its competitors and estimate their sales. The industry’s trade association often collect and publish total industry sales but it does not list individual company sales separately. In this way, each company can evaluate its performance against the industry as a whole. Suppose the company’s sales are increasing at 12%. This company actually is losing its relative position in the industry.
Market – 10 Main Entities which can be Marketed
A marketer does not only market goods and services, but he or she also markets eight other entities like Events, Experiences, Persons, Places, Properties, Organisations, Information and Ideas.
The ten entities, which can be marketed are as follows:
1. Goods:
Goods are physical, tangible articles, which can satisfy a need. All across the world, most of the country is engaged in manufacturing and producing goods like Toothpaste, Washing Powder, Cosmetics, Cars, Petrol etc.
Now, goods are not only marketed by companies, but also by individuals. In the era of Internet Marketing, individuals can also sell goods through the Internet. In India, you have got websites like www(dot)ebay(dot)in, www(dot)olx(dot)in to sell your products online. Besides these websites, goods can also be sold and bought through shopping sites like www(dot)flipkart(dot)come, www(dot)snapdeal(dot)com, www(dot)amazon(dot)in, www(dot)infibeam(dot)com, www(dot)homeshop18(dot)com, etc.
2. Services:
Services are non-physical and intangible in nature and can satisfy a need. Banking, Courier, Hotel, Airline, Multiplex, Train, Doctors, Lawyers, Management Consultants are all examples of services. With the advancement in the economy, a country moves from a good producing country to a service oriented country. For example, USA, which is one of the most developed countries in the world, is having a 70% – 30% mix of goods and services.
But some services are inclusive of product, like the restaurant, where a customer gets a tangible good in the form of say a masala dosa and gets it served at his table. In the other case, a service like mobile is backed by huge investments in equipments.
In the study of marketing all the ten entities, which can be marketed, are generally clubbed together as goods and services.
3. Experiences:
Experiences can be also marketed with the usage of goods, services and with a dose of technology. India’s first amusement park in Delhi – Appu Ghar, Essel World in Mumbai, and Disney Land in USA and Sentosa Island in Singapore are examples of experiences, which needs to be marketed.
4. Events:
Events like ICC Cricket World Cup 2015, FIFA World Cup Brazil 2014, Shahrukh Khan’s Temptation World Tour in 2009, Commonwealth Games in Delhi in 2010, Olympics, Asian Games, T20 World Cup, Wimbledon, Shakira’s Concerts etc. needs marketing to get the audience and spectators.
5. Persons:
Peter Montoya’s book ‘The Brand called You’ and Tom Peters’ advise to each person to become a brand, says a lot about the marketing of a person. For example, Mahendra Singh Dhoni, the captain of Indian Cricket Team, earned $10 million (Rs 48 Crore) in 2008 and became the world’s richest cricketer; followed by Sachin Tendulkar with $8 million (Rs 38.5 Crore). In 2007, the highest earning celebrity in the world was Oprah Winfrey with an earnings of $260 million. Other celebrities are also not far behind with Filmmaker Steven Spielberg earning $110 million, Sportsman Tiger Woods earning $100 million and Actor Johnny Depp earning $92 million.
All these celebrities are marketed by an agent or a personal manager or by a talent management company like Percept Talent Management; which manages Celebrities like Amitabh Bachchan, Shah Rukh Khan, Katrina Kaif, Aamir Khan, Priyanka Chopra, Yuvraj Singh, A. R. Rahman, Shekhar Suman besides others.
6. Places:
Incredible India, Kerala- The God’s Own Country, and Malaysia- Truly Asia, are different advertising campaigns to attract tourist to these places. Places are marketed to bring more tourists, residents, factories and offices. Tourism boards, real estate companies, advertising and promotional agencies and public relations organizations generally market the places.
7. Properties:
Properties including real estate properties and financial properties, both need to be marketed. Every Saturday, The Times of India comes out with a supplement called Times Property for the real estate properties to be marketed; while Hindustan Times comes out with HT Estates on the same day.
Companies like DLF, HDIL, Omaxe, Rahejas, Unitech etc. are real estate companies, who regularly market their real estate properties. Financial properties like shares, bonds, debentures, mutual funds etc. also need to be marketed to the individual as well as institutional investors.
8. Organisations:
Life is Good (LG), let us make things better (Philips), Experience Change (Videocon), Count on us (Maruti Suzuki) etc. are examples of fortifying the image of the company in the mind of its target publics. Even social organisations like CRY (Child Relief and You) also market themselves to gain visibility and attract funds.
9. Information:
Encyclopedia Britannica, Manorama Year Book, Penguin CNBC TV18 Business Year Book, Magazines like Overdrive, Smart Photography, Digit, Business World, Screen, Filmfare, Femina; and DVDs / CDs like Budget Demystified, Being Business Leaders are examples of how information is marketed. Schools, Colleges, Institutes and Universities also produce and market information to the students and their guardians.
10. Ideas:
‘An idea can change your life’ – the famous baseline of Idea Cellular fits correctly as far as marketing of ideas is concerned. Ideas like Condom ‘Bindaas Bol’ campaign, Oral Contraceptives ‘Goli Ke Jamjoli’ campaign, ‘Pulse Polio’ campaign, NACO campaign to spread awareness against AIDS etc. effectively market the social concerns by their respective bodies like USAID, Child and Reproductive health, Health ministry, Govt. of India and National AIDS Control Organisation (NACO).
Market – Benefits of External Market Access
The starting up of international activities is not only problems for the small and medium-sized enterprise. World market penetration has a series of actual benefits of different kinds (related to tax burden, customs, credits, etc.), which, in some cases, local entrepreneurs ignore.
1. Customs Benefits:
As regards customs advantages, most exports are benefited by a series of state stimula. The best known national incentives are tax refunds and drawbacks. They provide the reimbursement of internal taxes paid at each productive stage (in the case of tax refunds) and taxation corresponding to products imported by the company (in the case of drawbacks) that may affect exported product price.
Besides, each country has customs regulations that benefit international operations like- import and export temporary system, delivery in consignment, export on behalf of third parties, and use of free trade areas, among others.
2. Credit Benefits:
As regards the credit issue, there are special lines for exporters, granted by the main official and private banks. These credits are called pre-financing or financing export credits, and have more beneficial terms and rates than those assigned for domestic activity credits.
3. Tax Benefits:
From the taxation point of view, unlike sales made in the internal market, exports do not have to pay most of the main taxes like- Value Added Tax (VAT), Stamp Taxes,
Internal taxation, etc. Besides, as regards VAT, generally, exporting companies may—as regards tax paid in purchases and expenses—credit it, compensate with sales in the internal market, ask for a refund or transference.
The purpose of most States is to exempt international operations from domestic market operations taxes. Thus, the producer may form more competitive exportation prices without “exporting taxes”. There is a generally accepted principle in international marketing- “taxation in the country of destination”. The aim is to exempt exports from most taxes in the country of origin, so that the countries of destination could be the ones to tax the goods, through import operations.
4. Image Benefits:
The startup and consolidation of the small and medium enterprise international operations allow to generate a better company image. This affects the firm positioning in the external market. The internationalized enterprise assumes commitments in the different world markets and may supply the different requirements they make. This attitude gives the entrepreneur a higher status among the organizations in that sector and gives the company a position of prestige.
Besides, continuous contact with international operators, improves company’s image and symbol communication to the consumers, the competitors, and society in general. The internationalized company’s activities are positively perceived, especially world markets obstacle overcoming and responsibility and reliability in its management to assume commitments of great international importance and comply with them.
5. Market Diversification Benefits:
Another important incentive achieved by the exporting company comes from operation risk diversification between national and external markets. This issue may be more important when, due to national market crisis or economic recession, international scenarios are penetrated.
A national market with recession or economic depression makes entrepreneurs who have not gained access to world markets constantly affected by a decrease in sales and generates a productive capacity surplus.
A similar situation appears in those national markets in which there is a strong competitive environment which prevents the company from getting more participation in the domestic market. The same happens in saturated markets, in which the product is in its maturity or declination stage.
Every aspect described reinforces the importance that exportation has for small and medium- sized enterprises. The entrepreneur will be able to evaluate the possibility of penetrating other markets more interesting from the purchasing power point of view, with a greater number of consumers, or less saturated.
The organization will have to look for those environments with a lesser number of competitors than the domestic markets, or those country markets with different lifecycles for their product.
When external operations are developed, all the efforts and resources are not concentrated on the national market, and, in this way, the effects of internal market instability that may affect the business are diminished.
6. Benefits of Increase in Commercialized Volumes:
Certain price and quality competitiveness advantages can be obtained when products are internationally marketed. Besides, by getting an increase in earnings, exporting companies get other benefits. One of them is a better distribution of some fixed costs as a consequence of an increase in total sales that generates a greater production volume.
In this way more reduced fixed unitary costs and more competitive prices are accomplished (through economies of scale, economies of marketing and economies of R + D).
Besides, internationalization may solve problems of company idle capacity. The implementation of an international strategy allows to reach a greater production quality, because of the constant contact with other stricter cultures and with world environment competitors. Processes and product design are improved as international exposure is increased.
7. Benefits of Differentiation:
It is possible to discover that a particular product, in certain external markets, appears as a totally differentiated product from the rest. This situation may turn it into “unique”, be it for its technological advantages, design or provisions included. It may happen that a product is not very well-known in some markets or little used and consumed, as a result of being in the first stages of its lifecycle (for example, product introduction stage).
This issue may incentive penetration in that country-market with the company products. It should be verified that differential issues perceived upon certain attributes (quality, design, technology, costs, etc.) of a particular market product are about real differences and not erroneous perceptions.
8. Benefits of Exclusive Information:
An important factor that boosts exportation is the access to exclusive information about business opportunities in the world markets. These data may come from trade shows attendance, market informal studies, business trips or other means. They may be about specific orders from a particular country, about a specific product, or data concerning potential buyers. These elements represent an important advantage for the entrepreneur who possesses them, until they reach competitors’ hands.
9. Benefits of Associativity:
When an export company strategy is used through different joint structures (like consortia, cooperatives, etc.), the enterprise may hire technical personnel specially qualified in different international activities (market studies, international quality certifications, trade shows attendance, etc.). Without taking part in those associations it would be very difficult to pay for those expenses individually.
Besides, synergy (consistent union of forces) among the different exporting partners of the project is produced, which allows to get better negotiating conditions with the international marketing different operators and auxiliaries (clients, suppliers, carriers, customs agents, etc.). Each member is contained by a company structure of cooperation in the international access stages.
In some cases, some enterprises opt to export by imitating their competitors’ attitude because they have already internationalized. Thus, they try not to be left aside from the relative advantages of the international marketing enjoyed by International Marketing the competition. However, in some countries, especially in the developing countries, the presence of small-sized companies in the international environment continues being absolutely limited.
It is important to reflect on the relevance of international markets and the advantages of positioning, in order to adopt a positive attitude to internationalization. The assumption of external commitment has to be gradual and decisions must be adopted beyond the present state of affairs that may affect companies.
Entrepreneurial attitude must not be based on the marketing of balances not sold in the internal market (exportable balance). There has to be a strategy to allow the exportation of stable and continuous volumes (exportable offer), to generate lasting commercial relationships with customers abroad.
Market Survey
Meaning of Market Survey:
Small firms are over and over again reluctant to invest in market research exercise as it seems to be an expensive proportion. Moreover, it is a time-taking process, and an entrepreneurial business enterprise is usually in urgency.
Many entrepreneurial ventures take a middle path and decide to undertake market research when there is a big decision to be taken. This is not necessarily the right approach. The question of when to resort to market research can be answered by a cost-benefit analysis.
The costs of doing market research are the direct expenses of doing research as well as the likely loss in sales due to delaying decision. A delay in the decision caused by waiting for the results of the market research can give an opportunity to competitors to capture market share at your cost.
Market research is not to be confused with field survey. Afield survey is just one of the techniques used in market research. Any dependable information that improves the marketing decision is market research.
What is a Market Survey?
The firm market survey is used by some as synonymous with market research or market analysis. This is incorrect. Market survey is only a technique or method of market research or market analysis. Its purpose is to collect specific data concerning the market that cannot be had from the company’s internal records or from external published sources of data.
When a market survey is used for generating relevant market information and such information forms the basis of the sales forecasts, the forecasting method is referred to as the market survey method of sales forecasting.
Why Need Market Survey?
Normally, when an enterprise wants to introduce a new product or an improved product, it resorts to a market survey to assess the likely demand for the product. Marketing a new product is not an easy job and a novice can very easily be thrown out by other competitors.
To chalk out a programme for marketing a new product is therefore, necessary. A new article is one which has not been previously marketed by any other business concern, e.g., new drink, new toilet soap, new hair oil, new type of cloth and a new machine, etc.
Whereas a new brand is simply a competitor among other products of that type already available on the market. For a new brand it is necessary to find out merely whether the market is being adequately served or whether there is room for another brand. For a new product it is necessary to find out whether a market does exist and if it does not, whether it is possible to create a market for the product. Likewise, any new enterprise entering the market for the first time, resort to the market survey method for forecasting its demand/sales.
This is quite natural. The enterprise does not have any data of past sales demand patterns to fall back upon. It has to gather the information from the market and take decisions. Usually, the enterprise conducts a survey among a sample of consumers and gauges their attitude, likely purchase, purchase habits, etc. The merit of the market survey method lies in the fact that the method facilitates gathering of original or primary data, i.e., specific to the problem on hand. The main demerit is that it is time- consuming and expensive.
Techniques of Market Survey:
Usually the following techniques are used to collect factual data, less so when used to gain insight into respondent’s interpretations.
The market survey techniques may be of the following types:
1. Product-Oriented:
A product needs proper planning by the entrepreneur before its introduction in the market. The purpose is to offer better service and satisfaction to customers. Today’s marketing firms are selling product’s benefits and image rather than the product itself.
Product-oriented survey techniques help in gathering essential facts about the product.
It entails finding answers to the following:
(i) What fundamental human instincts does the use or consumption of the product satisfy?
(ii) What interests and desires does it appeal to?
(iii) How well does it meet the requirement of the user or consumer?
(iv) Can any improvements or modifications be made which would strengthen its appeal?
(v) Are there any use for it not hither to thought of?
(vi) What are its selling points?
(vii) What should be the unit or unit of sale?
Even while selecting the methods of marketing and the channels of distribution the following question certainly will do an impressive job:
(i) Will it be better to employ salesmen alone?
(ii) Should it use advertising alone?
(iii) To use a combination?
(iv) What subsidiary forms of selling should be used?
(v) What will be the relative costs of marketing by these methods?
(vi) Should the product be sold to the consumer or user through the manufacturer’s organisation?
(vii) Through retailers?
(viii) Would the employment of wholesalers be advantageous?
(ix) What would be the benefits of using special selling agents?
(x) What are the relative costs and net profits likely to be as a result of using each of these methods?
2. Market-Oriented:
Now, the customers were not ready to buy whatever was offered to them by the entrepreneurs. They started to buy the goods or service that was more beneficial to them in terms of quality, price, satisfaction, durability, look and soon. Therefore, the entrepreneurs were compelled to produce what the customers want.
An entrepreneur should seek answer to the following raised questions in order to have strong standing in the market:
(i) Who are its logical consumers?
(ii) Who are its marginal consumers?
(iii) Where are they to be found?
(iv) Who are its logical distributors?
Expected Investigation:
(i) What type of investigation will suit the product?
(ii) By whom will it be conducted?
(iii) Exactly what information should be sought for?
(iv) What size of sample should be considered as sufficiently indicative?
(v) Are there any existing product which might give some indication of size of the market and volume of sales to be expected?
(vi) How should the product be packed?
(vii) What prices should it be sold?
(viii) What terms would be most satisfactory to dealers and manufacturers?
(ix) What class of dealers should handle the product?
3. Desk Research:
The terms ‘Desk Research’ denotes all marketing researches done by a marketing expert/entrepreneur with the help of published and other written sources of information. It is a table work involving the analysis of data available in directories, journals and magazines and in the internal records of the firms such as final statements, sales reports and so on.
Advantages:
(i) Information is available without much effort.
(ii) The method is least expensive.
(iii) The data are free from investigator’s bias.
(iv) It keeps the marketing manager free from botheration of field investigation.
(v) The data available from government, stock exchange, chamber of commerce and industry and other organized bodies is also reliable to a great extent.
Disadvantages:
(i) This is based on secondary data, therefore limitations of secondary data is involved in them.
(ii) Published information will have to be modified to meet the requirement of the entrepreneur/ researcher before using it.
(iii) It is less reliable and results are doubtful unless tested by field investigation.
4. Field Investigation:
Field investigation is a very reliable technique as it is based on primary data collected directly by the researcher/entrepreneur from the field. Sometimes, the primary data is supplemented with secondary or published data too.
There are three field research techniques:
(a) Mail Order Surveys:
A mail order survey is a complete antithesis of the personal interviews. Under this method, a questionnaire which is sent to him by mail is completed by informant completely unaided and unguided. Under this method, the questionnaire should be carefully compiled, structured and pre-tested, as it will have to be filled in by the informant himself.
The names and addresses of people to whom questionnaire are sent by post are obtained by various means. There are agencies which specialize in providing list of different kinds of people such as lawyers, doctors, engineers, government officers, professors and so forth. The simplest list is of course the telephone directory. But it cannot be an exhaustive list.
(b) Telephone Surveys:
Telephone interviewing is the second type of field research. This technique has been used in particular for the estimation of the number of persons who have just finished watching a television programme or listening to a radio broadcast. This is also used to estimate quickly to ascertain the ownership of different types of product. Though this method is very convenient for industrial surveys, it is not widely used in this country.
(c) Personal Interviews:
The third technique of field investigation is personal interviewing. Under this technique, the interviewer follows a rigid procedure in asking question in prescribed form and order. A structured questionnaire is prepared and the interviewer fills it on the basis of answers supplied by the informant. The interviewer may, however, be allowed varying degrees of freedom in conducting the interview.
The greater the freedom allowed, the higher is the skill required in the interviewer and the more complex are the problems of analysis of the results. These interviews may be of various type-structured, semi-structured, unstructured, the free interview, the focus interview, depth interview and so on. Every type of interview has its own merits and demerits. Interviewing method is quite popular in conducting marketing researches in India and abroad.
5. The Delphi Technique:
The Delphi Technique was originally conceived as a way to obtain the opinion of experts without necessarily bringing them together face to face. In recent times, however, it has taken on an all new meaning and purpose. The Delphi Technique is the method being used to squeeze citizens out of the process, affecting a left-wing takeover of the schools.
The change agent or facilitator goes through the motions of acting as an organizer, getting each person in the target group to elicit expression of their concerns about a program, project, or policy in question. The facilitator listens attentively, forms “task forces,” “urges everyone to make lists,” and so on. While she/he is doing this, the facilitator learns something about each member of the target group. She/he identifies the “leaders,” the loud mouths,” as well as those who frequently turn sides during the argument – the “weak or noncommittal”.
This technique is a very unethical method of achieving consensus on a controversial topic in group settings. It requires well-trained professionals who deliberately escalate tension among group members, pitting one faction against the other, so as to make one viewpoint appear ridiculous so the other becomes “sensible” whether such is warranted or not.
The Delphi technique is one more way of obtaining group input for ideas and problem-solving. Unlike the nominal group process, the Delphi does not require face to face participation. It uses a series of carefully designed questionnaires interspersed with information summaries and feedback from preceding responses.
In a planning situation, the Delphi can be used to:
i. Develop a number of alternatives;
ii. Assess the social and economic impacts of rapid community growth;
iii. Explore underlying assumptions or background information leading to different judgments;
iv. Seek out information on which agreement may later be generated;
v. Correlate informed judgments on a subject involving many disciplines; and
vi. Educate respondents on the diverse and interrelated elements of a topic.
The Delphi begins with the initial development of a questionnaire focusing on the identified problem. An appropriate respondent group is selected, and then the questionnaire is mailed to them. Each participant answers the questionnaire independently and returns it. The initiators of the questionnaire summarize responses, and then develop a feedback summary and a second questionnaire for the same respondent group.
After reviewing the feedback summary, respondents independently rate priority ideas included in the second questionnaire, then mail back the responses. The process is repeated until investigators feel positions are firm and agreement on a topic is reached. A final summary report is issued to the respondent group. The Delphi can be modified in many ways.
In assessing community needs, the Delphi technique could be used for many of the same things as the nominal group process-determining and prioritizing community problems; setting goals; designing needs assessment strategies; planning a conference or community forum; developing improved community services; evaluating alternative plans for community development; or aggregating judgments of special-interest or mutually hostile group.
Advantages and Disadvantages of the Delphi Technique for community need assessment.
Advantages:
i. Allows participants to remain anonymous.
ii. Inexpensive.
iii. Free of social pressure, personality influence and individual dominance.
iv. A reliable judgment or forecast results.
v. Allows sharing of information and reasoning among participants.
vi. Conducive to independent thinking and gradual formulation.
vii. A well-selected respondent panel – a mix of local official, knowledgeable individuals, members of impacted community regional officials, academic social officials academic social scientists etc., – can provide a broad analytical perspective on potential growth impacts.
viii. Can be used to reach consensus among groups hostile to each other.
Disadvantages:
i. Judgments are those of a selected group of people and may not be representative.
ii. Tendency to eliminate extreme positions and force a middle-of-the-road consensus.
iii. More time-consuming than the group process method.
iv. Should not be viewed as a total solution to forecasting.
v. Requires skill in written communication.
vi. Requires adequate time and participant commitment (about 30-45 days).
Page load link
Go to Top
«Market forces» redirects here. For the novel by Richard Morgan, see Market Forces. For other uses, see Market.
In economics, a market is a composition of systems, institutions, procedures, social relations or infrastructures whereby parties engage in exchange. While parties may exchange goods and services by barter, most markets rely on sellers offering their goods or services (including labour power) to buyers in exchange for money. It can be said that a market is the process by which the prices of goods and services are established. Markets facilitate trade and enable the distribution and allocation of resources in a society. Markets allow any tradeable item to be evaluated and priced. A market emerges more or less spontaneously or may be constructed deliberately by human interaction in order to enable the exchange of rights (cf. ownership) of services and goods. Markets generally supplant gift economies and are often held in place through rules and customs, such as a booth fee, competitive pricing, and source of goods for sale (local produce or stock registration).
Markets can differ by products (goods, services) or factors (labour and capital) sold, product differentiation, place in which exchanges are carried, buyers targeted, duration, selling process, government regulation, taxes, subsidies, minimum wages, price ceilings, legality of exchange, liquidity, intensity of speculation, size, concentration, exchange asymmetry, relative prices, volatility and geographic extension. The geographic boundaries of a market may vary considerably, for example the food market in a single building, the real estate market in a local city, the consumer market in an entire country, or the economy of an international trade bloc where the same rules apply throughout. Markets can also be worldwide, see for example the global diamond trade. National economies can also be classified as developed markets or developing markets.
In mainstream economics, the concept of a market is any structure that allows buyers and sellers to exchange any type of goods, services and information. The exchange of goods or services, with or without money, is a transaction.[1] Market participants consist of all the buyers and sellers of a good who influence its price, which is a major topic of study of economics and has given rise to several theories and models concerning the basic market forces of supply and demand. A major topic of debate is how much a given market can be considered to be a «free market», that is free from government intervention. Microeconomics traditionally focuses on the study of market structure and the efficiency of market equilibrium; when the latter (if it exists) is not efficient, then economists say that a market failure has occurred. However, it is not always clear how the allocation of resources can be improved since there is always the possibility of government failure.
Definition[edit]
In economics, a market is a coordinating mechanism that uses prices to convey information among economic entities (such as firms, households and individuals) to regulate production and distribution. In his seminal 1937 article «The Nature of the Firm», Ronald Coase wrote: «An economist thinks of the economic system as being coordinated by the price mechanism….in economic theory we find that the allocation of factors of production between different uses is determined by the price mechanism».[2] Thus the usage of the price mechanism to convey information is the defining feature of the market. This is in contrast to a firm, which as Coase put it, «the distinguishing mark of the firm is the super-session of the price mechanism».[2]
Thus, Firms and Markets are two opposite forms of organizing production; Coase wrote:[2]
Outside the firm, price movements direct production, which is co-ordinated through a series of exchange transactions on the market. Within a firm, these market transactions are eliminated and in place of the complicated market structure with exchange transactions is substituted the entrepreneur-co-ordinator, who directs production.
There are also other hybrid forms of coordinating mechanisms, in between the hierarchical firm and price-coordinating market(e.g. global value chains, Business Ventures, Joint Venture, and strategic alliances).
The reasons for the existence of firms or other forms of co-ordinating mechanisms of production and distribution alongside the market are studied in «The Theory of the Firm» literature, with various complete and incomplete contract theories trying to explain the existence of the firm. Incomplete contract theories that are explicitly based on bounded rationality lead to the costs of writing complete contracts. Such theories include: Transaction Cost Economies [3] by Oliver Williamson and Residual Rights Theory[4] by Groomsman, Hart, and Moore.
Market-Firms’s dichotomy can be contrasted with the relationship between the agents transacting. While in a market the relationship is short term and restricted to the contract, in the case of firms and other co-ordinating mechanisms it is for a longer duration.[5]
In the modern world much economic activity takes place through fiat and not the market. Lafontaine and Slade (2007) estimates, in the US, that the total value added in transactions inside the firms equal the total value added of all market transactions.[6] Similarly, 80% of all World Trade is conducted under Global Value Chains (2012 estimate), while 33% (1996 estimate) is intra-firm trade.[7][8] Nearly 50% of US imports and 30% of exports take place within firms.[9] While Rajan and Zingales (1998) have found that in 43 countries two-thirds of the growth in value added between 1980 and 1990 came from increase in firm size.[10]
Types[edit]
A market is one of the many varieties of systems, institutions, procedures, social relations and infrastructures whereby parties engage in exchange. While parties may exchange goods and services by barter, most markets rely on sellers offering their goods or services (including labour) in exchange for money from buyers. It can be said that a market is the process by which the prices of goods and services are established. Markets facilitate trade and enable the distribution and allocation of resources in a society. Markets allow any trade-able item to be evaluated and priced. A market sometimes emerges more or less spontaneously or may be constructed deliberately by human interaction in order to enable the exchange of rights (cf. ownership) of services and goods.
Markets of varying types can spontaneously arise whenever a party has interest in a good or service that some other party can provide. Hence there can be a market for cigarettes in correctional facilities, another for chewing gum in a playground, and yet another for contracts for the future delivery of a commodity. There can be black markets, where a good is exchanged illegally, for example markets for goods under a command economy despite pressure to repress them and virtual markets, such as eBay, in which buyers and sellers do not physically interact during negotiation. A market can be organized as an auction, as a private electronic market, as a commodity wholesale market, as a shopping center, as complex institutions such as international markets and as an informal discussion between two individuals.
Markets vary in form, scale (volume and geographic reach), location and types of participants as well as the types of goods and services traded. The following is a non exhaustive list:
Physical consumer markets[edit]
Front view of Stuart Saunders Hogg Market, Kolkata
- Food retail markets: farmers’ markets, fish markets, wet markets and grocery stores
- Retail marketplaces: public markets, market squares, Main Streets, High Streets, bazaars, souqs, night markets, shopping strip malls and shopping malls
- Big-box stores: supermarkets, hypermarkets and discount stores
- Ad hoc auction markets: process of buying and selling goods or services by offering them up for bid, taking bids and then selling the item to the highest bidder
- Used goods markets such as flea markets
- Temporary markets such as fairs
- Real estate markets
Physical business markets[edit]
- Physical wholesale markets: sale of goods or merchandise to retailers; to industrial, commercial, institutional, or other professional business users or to other wholesalers and related subordinated services
- Markets for intermediate goods used in production of other goods and services
- Labour markets: where people sell their labour to businesses in exchange for a wage
- Online auctions and Ad hoc auction markets: process of buying and selling goods or services by offering them up for bid, taking bids and then selling the item to the highest bidder
- Temporary markets such as trade fairs
- Energy markets
Non-physical markets[edit]
- Media markets (broadcast market): is a region where the population can receive the same (or similar) television and radio station offerings and may also include other types of media including newspapers and Internet content
- Internet markets (electronic commerce): trading in products or services using computer networks, such as the Internet
- Artificial markets created by regulation to exchange rights for derivatives that have been designed to ameliorate externalities, such as pollution permits (see carbon trading)
Financial markets[edit]
Financial markets facilitate the exchange of liquid assets. Most investors prefer investing in two markets:
- The stock markets, for the exchange of shares in corporations (NYSE, AMEX and the NASDAQ are the most common stock markets in the United States)
- The bond markets
There are also:
- Currency markets are used to trade one currency for another, and are often used for speculation on currency exchange rates
- The money market is the name for the global market for lending and borrowing
- Futures markets, where contracts are exchanged regarding the future delivery of goods
- Prediction markets are a type of speculative market in which the goods exchanged are futures on the occurrence of certain events; they apply the market dynamics to facilitate information aggregation
- Insurance markets
- Debt markets
[edit]
- Grey markets (parallel markets): is the trade of a commodity through distribution channels which, while legal, are unofficial, unauthorized, or unintended by the original manufacturer[citation needed]
- markets in illegal goods such as the market for illicit drugs, illegal arms, infringing products, cigarettes sold to minors or untaxed cigarettes (in some jurisdictions), or the private sale of unpasteurized goat milk[11]
Mechanisms[edit]
Cabbage market by Václav Malý
In economics, a market that runs under laissez-faire policies is called a free market, it is «free» from the government, in the sense that the government makes no attempt to intervene through taxes, subsidies, minimum wages, price ceilings and so on. However, market prices may be distorted by a seller or sellers with monopoly power, or a buyer with monopsony power. Such price distortions can have an adverse effect on market participant’s welfare and reduce the efficiency of market outcomes. The relative level of organization and negotiating power of buyers and sellers also markedly affects the functioning of the market.
Markets are a system and systems have structure. The structure of a well-functioning market is defined by the theory of perfect competition. Well-functioning markets of the real world are never perfect, but basic structural characteristics can be approximated for real world markets, for example:
- Many small buyers and sellers
- Buyers and sellers have equal access to information
- Products are comparable
Markets where price negotiations meet equilibrium, but the equilibrium is not efficient are said to experience market failure. Market failures are often associated with time-inconsistent preferences, information asymmetries, non-perfectly competitive markets, principal–agent problems, externalities, or public goods. Among the major negative externalities which can occur as a side effect of production and market exchange, are air pollution (side-effect of manufacturing and logistics) and environmental degradation (side-effect of farming and urbanization).
There exists a popular thought, especially among economists, that free markets would have a structure of a perfect competition.[citation needed] The logic behind this thought is that market failure is thought to be caused by other exogenic systems, and after removing those exogenic systems («freeing» the markets) the free markets could run without market failures.[citation needed] For a market to be competitive, there must be more than a single buyer or seller. It has been suggested that two people may trade, but it takes at least three persons to have a market so that there is competition in at least one of its two sides.[12] However, competitive markets—as understood in formal economic theory—rely on much larger numbers of both buyers and sellers. A market with a single seller and multiple buyers is a monopoly. A market with a single buyer and multiple sellers is a monopsony. These are «the polar opposites of perfect competition».[13] As an argument against such logic, there is a second view that suggests that the source of market failures is inside the market system itself, therefore the removal of other interfering systems would not result in markets with a structure of perfect competition. As an analogy, such an argument may suggest that capitalists do not want to enhance the structure of markets, just like a coach of a football team would influence the referees or would break the rules if he could while he is pursuing his target of winning the game. Thus, according to this view, capitalists are not enhancing the balance of their team versus the team of consumer-workers, so the market system needs a «referee» from outside that balances the game. In this second framework, the role of a «referee» of the market system is usually to be given to a democratic government.
Research[edit]
Disciplines such as sociology, economic history, economic geography and marketing developed novel understandings of markets[14] studying actual existing markets made up of persons interacting in diverse ways in contrast to an abstract and all-encompassing concepts of «the market». The term «the market» is generally used in two ways:
- «The market» denotes the abstract mechanisms whereby supply and demand confront each other and deals are made; in its place, reference to markets reflects ordinary experience and the places, processes and institutions in which exchanges occurs[15]
- «The market» signifies an integrated, all-encompassing and cohesive capitalist world economy.
Economics[edit]
Political economy[edit]
Economics used to be called political economy, as Adam Smith defined it in The Wealth of Nations:[16]
Political economy, considered as a branch of the science of a statesman or legislator, proposes two distinct objects; first, to provide a plentiful revenue or subsistence for the people, or, more properly, to enable them to provide such a revenue or subsistence for themselves; and, secondly, to supply the state or commonwealth with a revenue sufficient for the public services. It proposes to enrich both the people and the sovereign.
The earliest works of political economy are usually attributed to the British scholars Adam Smith, Thomas Malthus, and David Ricardo, although they were preceded by the work of the French physiocrats, such as François Quesnay (1694–1774) and Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot (1727–1781). Smith describes how exchange of goods arose:[17]
«As it is by treaty, by barter, and by purchase, that we obtain from one another the greater part of those mutual good offices which we stand in need of, so it is this same trucking disposition which originally gives occasion to the division of labour. In a tribe of hunters or shepherds, a particular person makes bows and arrows, for example, with more readiness and dexterity than any other. He frequently exchanges them for cattle or for venison, with his companions; and he finds at last that he can, in this manner, get more cattle and venison, than if he himself went to the field to catch them. From a regard to his own interest, therefore, the making of bows and arrows grows to be his chief business, and he becomes a sort of armourer. Another excels in making the frames and covers of their little huts or moveable houses. He is accustomed to be of use in this way to his neighbours, who reward him in the same manner with cattle and with venison, till at last he finds it his interest to dedicate himself entirely to this employment, and to become a sort of house-carpenter. In the same manner a third becomes a smith or a brazier; a fourth, a tanner or dresser of hides or skins, the principal part of the clothing of savages. And thus the certainty of being able to exchange all that surplus part of the produce of his own labour, which is over and above his own consumption, for such parts of the produce of other men’s labour as he may have occasion for, encourages every man to apply himself to a particular occupation, and to cultivate and bring to perfection whatever talent of genius he may possess for that particular species of business.»
And explains how exchanged mediated by money came to dominate the market:[18]
«But when barter ceases, and money has become the common instrument of commerce, every particular commodity is more frequently exchanged for money than for any other commodity. The butcher seldom carries his beef or his mutton to the baker or the brewer, in order to exchange them for bread or for beer; but he carries them to the market, where he exchanges them for money, and afterwards exchanges that money for bread and for beer. The quantity of money which he gets for them regulates, too, the quantity of bread and beer which he can afterwards purchase. It is more natural and obvious to him, therefore, to estimate their value by the quantity of money, the commodity for which he immediately exchanges them, than by that of bread and beer, the commodities for which he can exchange them only by the intervention of another commodity; and rather to say that his butcher’s meat is worth three-pence or fourpence a-pound, than that it is worth three or four pounds of bread, or three or four quarts of small beer. Hence it comes to pass, that the exchangeable value of every commodity is more frequently estimated by the quantity of money, than by the quantity either of labour or of any other commodity which can be had in exchange for it.»
Microeconomics[edit]
Microeconomics (from Greek prefix mikro— meaning «small» and economics) is a branch of economics that studies the behavior of individuals and small impacting organizations in making decisions on the allocation of limited resources (see scarcity). On the other hand, macroeconomics (from the Greek prefix makro— meaning «large» and economics) is a branch of economics dealing with the performance, structure, behavior and decision-making of an economy as a whole, rather than individual markets.
Marginal revolution[edit]
An Afghan market teeming with vendors and shoppers
The modern field of microeconomics arose as an effort of neoclassical economics school of thought to put economic ideas into mathematical mode. It began in the 19th century debates surrounding the works of Antoine Augustin Cournot, William Stanley Jevons, Carl Menger and Léon Walras—this period is usually denominated as the Marginal Revolution. A recurring theme of these debates was the contrast between the labor theory of value and the subjective theory of value, the former being associated with classical economists such as Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Karl Marx (Marx was a contemporary of the marginalists). A labour theory of value can be understood as a theory that argues that economic value is determined by the amount of socially necessary labour time while a subjective theory of value derives economic value from subjective preferences, usually by specifying a utility function in accordance with utilitarian philosophy.
In his Principles of Economics (1890),[19] Alfred Marshall presented a possible solution to this problem, using the supply and demand model. Marshall’s idea of solving the controversy was that the demand curve could be derived by aggregating individual consumer demand curves, which were themselves based on the consumer problem of maximizing utility. The supply curve could be derived by superimposing a representative firm supply curves for the factors of production and then market equilibrium (economic equivalent of mechanical equilibrium) would be given by the intersection of demand and supply curves. He also introduced the notion of different market periods: mainly long run and short run. This set of ideas gave way to what economists call perfect competition—now found in the standard microeconomics texts, even though Marshall himself was highly skeptical it could be used as general model of all markets.
Market structure[edit]
Opposed to the model of perfect competition, some models of imperfect competition were proposed:
- The monopoly model, already considered by marginalist economists, describes a profit maximizing capitalist facing a market demand curve with no competitors, who may practice price discrimination.
- Oligopoly is a market form in which a market or industry is dominated by a small number of sellers. The oldest model was the spring water duopoly of Cournot (1838) [20] in which equilibrium is determined by the duopolists reactions functions. It was criticized by Harold Hotelling for its instability, by Joseph Bertrand for lacking equilibrium for prices as independent variables.
- Monopolistic competition is a type of imperfect competition such that many producers sell products that are differentiated from one another (e.g., by branding or quality) and hence are not perfect substitutes. In monopolistic competition, a firm takes the prices charged by its rivals as given and ignores the impact of its own prices on the prices of other firms. The «founding father» of the theory of monopolistic competition is Edward Hastings Chamberlin, who wrote a pioneering book on the subject, Theory of Monopolistic Competition (1933). Joan Robinson published a book called The Economics of Imperfect Competition with a comparable theme of distinguishing perfect from imperfect competition. Chamberlin defined monopolistic competition as «challenge to traditional viewpoint of economics that competition and monopoly are alternatives and that individual prices are to be explained in terms of one or the other». He continues: «By contrast it is held that most economic situations are composite of both competition and monopoly, and that, wherever this is the case, a false view is given by neglecting either one of the two forces and regarding the situation as made up entirely of the other».[21] Hotelling built a model of market located over a line with two sellers in each extreme of the line, in this case maximizing profit for both sellers leads to a stable equilibrium. From this model also follows that if a seller is to choose the location of his store so as to maximize his profit, he will place his store the closest to his competitor as «the sharper competition with his rival is offset by the greater number of buyers he has an advantage».[22] He also argues that clustering of stores is wasteful from the point of view of transportation costs and that public interest would dictate more spatial dispersion.
- William Baumol provided in his 1977 paper[23] the current formal definition of a natural monopoly where “an industry in which multifirm production is more costly than production by a monopoly”.
- Baumol defined a contestable market in his 1982 paper[24] as a market where «entry is absolutely free and exit absolutely costless», freedom of entry in Stigler sense: the incumbent has no cost discrimination against entrants. He states that a contestable market will never have an economic profit greater than zero when in equilibrium and the equilibrium will also be efficient. According to Baumol, this equilibrium emerges endogenously due to the nature of contestable markets; that is, the only industry structure that survives in the long run is the one which minimizes total costs. This is in contrast to the older theory of industry structure since not only is industry structure not exogenously given, but equilibrium is reached without an ad hoc hypothesis on the behavior of firms, say using reaction functions in a duopoly. He concludes the paper commenting that regulators that seek to impede entry and/or exit of firms would do better to not interfere if the market in question resembles a contestable market.
Market failure[edit]
Used cars market: due to presence of fundamental asymmetrical information between seller and buyer the market equilibrium is not efficient—in the language of economists it is a market failure
Around the 1970s the study of market failures came into focus with the study of information asymmetry. In particular, three authors emerged from this period: Akerlof, Spence and Stiglitz. Akerlof considered the problem of bad quality cars driving good quality cars out of the market in his classic «The Market for Lemons» (1970) because of the presence of asymmetrical information between buyers and sellers.[25] Michael Spence explained that signaling was fundamental in the labour market since employers can’t know beforehand which candidate is the most productive, a college degree becomes a signaling device that a firm uses to select new personnel.[26] Stiglitz provided some general conditions under which market equilibrium is not efficient: presence of externalities, imperfect information and incomplete markets.[27]
State interference[edit]
György Lukács, a founder of Western Marxism wrote about the essence of commodity-structure:.[28]
Before tackling the problem itself we must be quite clear in our minds that commodity fetishism is a specific problem of our age, the age of modern capitalism. Commodity exchange an the corresponding subjective and objective commodity relations existed, as we know, when society was still very primitive. What is at issue here, however, is the question: how far is commodity exchange together with its structural consequences able to influence the total outer and inner life of society? Thus the extent to which such exchange is the dominant form of metabolic change in a society cannot simply be treated in quantitative terms — as would harmonize with the modern modes of thought already eroded by the reifying effects of the dominant commodity form. The distinction between a society where this form is dominant, permeating every expression of life, and a society where it only makes an episodic appearance is essentially one of quality. For depending on which is the case, all the subjective phenomena in the societies concerned are objectified in qualitatively different ways.
Human labour is abstracted and incorporated in commodities:[29]
- Objectively: is so far as the commodity form facilitates the equal exchange of qualitatively different things
- Subjectively: human labour is both the common factor to which all commodities are reduced (in the abstract) and the principle governing the actual production of commodities (in reality)
The ultimate problem for the thought of the bourgeoisie is the crisis: the qualitative existence of the ‘things’ misunderstood as use-values become the decisive factor. The failure is characteristic of classical economics and bourgeoisie economics, inadequate at explaining the true movement of economic activity in toto. The state has a system of law corresponding to capitalist needs: bureaucracy, formal standardization of justice and civil service.[28]
C. B. Macpherson identifies an underlying model of the market underlying Anglo-American liberal democratic political economy and philosophy in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries: persons are cast as self-interested individuals, who enter into contractual relations with other such individuals, concerning the exchange of goods or personal capacities cast as commodities, with the motive of maximizing pecuniary interest. The state and its governance systems are cast as outside of this framework.[30] This model came to dominant economic thinking in the later nineteenth century, as so called liberal economists such as Ricardo, Mill, Jevons, Walras and later neo-classical economics shifted from reference to geographically located marketplaces to an abstract «market».[31] This tradition is continued in contemporary neoliberalism epitomised by the Mont Pelerin Society which gathered Frederick Hayek, Ludwig von Mises, Milton Friedman and Karl Popper, where the market is held up as optimal for wealth creation and human freedom and the states’ role imagined as minimal, reduced to that of upholding and keeping stable property rights, contract and money supply. According to David Harvey, this allowed for boilerplate economic and institutional restructuring under structural adjustment and post-Communist reconstruction.[32] Similar formalism occurs in a wide variety of social democratic and Marxist discourses that situate political action as antagonistic to the market.
A central theme of empirical analyses is the variation and proliferation of types of markets since the rise of capitalism and global scale economies. The Regulation school stresses the ways in which developed capitalist countries have implemented varying degrees and types of environmental, economic and social regulation, taxation and public spending, fiscal policy and government provisioning of goods, all of which have transformed markets in uneven and geographical varied ways and created a variety of mixed economies.
Economic coordination[edit]
Drawing on concepts of institutional variance and path dependence, varieties of capitalism theorists (such as Peter Hall and David Soskice) identify two dominant modes of economic ordering in the developed capitalist countries:
- Coordinated market economies (such as Germany and Japan) based on relational or incomplete contracting, network monitoring based on the exchange of private information inside networks, and more reliance on collaborative, as opposed to competitive, relationships to build the competencies of the firm
- Anglo-American liberal market economies: firms coordinate their activities primarily via hierarchies and competitive market arrangements.
A coal power plant in Datteln—emissions trading or cap and trade is a market-based approach used to control pollution by providing economic incentives for achieving reductions in the emissions of pollutants
However, such approaches imply that the Anglo-American liberal market economies in fact operate in a matter close to the abstract notion of «the market». While Anglo-American countries have seen increasing introduction of neo-liberal forms of economic ordering, this has not led to simple convergence, but rather a variety of hybrid institutional orderings.[33] Rather, a variety of new markets have emerged, such as for carbon trading or rights to pollute. In some cases, such as emerging markets for water in England and Wales, different forms of neoliberalism have been tried: moving from the state hydraulic model associated with concepts of universal provision and public service to market environmentalism associated with pricing of environmental externalities to reduce environmental degradation and efficient allocation of water resources. In this case liberalization has multiple meanings:
- Privatization: change of ownership from state monopoly to private hands
- Commercialization: pursuing efficiency, cost-benefit analysis and profit maximization by introducing prices in comparison with the bill system proportional to property value
- Commodification: standardization, pricing to address water scarcity according to the Dublin principles and the Hague declaration
In a period of fiscal and ideological crisis, state failure is seen as the catalyst for liberalization, however the failure in assuring water quality can be seen as a driver for economic and ecological reregulation (in this case coming from the European Union). More broadly the idea of a water market failure can seen as the explanation for state intervention, generating a natural monopoly of hydraulic infrastructure and the regulation of externalities such as water pollution. The situation however is not that simple, as the regulator may have the duty of introducing competition, which can be:
- Direct competition or product competition
- Surrogate competition
- Competition for corporate control by mergers and takeovers
- Procurement competition
- Franchising
Introduction of metering can result in both restriction and increase of consumption with LRMC pricing being the regulator (Ofwat) preferred methodology.[34]
Marketing[edit]
Market distribution[edit]
Paul Dulaney Converse and Fred M. Jones wrote:[35]
Market distribution includes those activities which create place, time, and possession utilities. To the economist, market distribution is therefore part of production because it deals with the creation of utilities, and “distribution” refers to the distribution of wealth among the members of society. The businessman, however, thinks of distribution as selling his goods and getting them into the hands of the consumer. To the businessman, “distribution” means marketing—selling and transportation.
The methods of studying marketing are:
- Functional approach: services or functions performed, what goods they are performed upon, what middlemen perform them
- Commodity approach: what goods are marketed, what function are performed on them, what middlemen perform these functions
- Institutional approach: what institutions, or middlemen, are engaged in distribution, what functions they perform, what good they handle
Businesses market their products/services to a specific segments of consumers: the defining factors of the markets are determined by demographics, interests and age/gender. A small market is a niche market, while a big market is a mass market. A form of expansion is to enter a new market and sell/advertise to a different set of users.
Marketing management[edit]
The marketing management school, evolved in the late 1950s and early 1960s, is fundamentally linked with the marketing mix[36] framework, a business tool used in marketing and by marketers. In his paper «The Concept of the Marketing Mix», Neil H. Borden reconstructed the history of the term «marketing mix».[37][38] He started teaching the term after an associate, James Culliton, described the role of the marketing manager in 1948 as a «mixer of ingredients»; one who sometimes follows recipes prepared by others, sometimes prepares his own recipe as he goes along, sometimes adapts a recipe from immediately available ingredients, and at other times invents new ingredients no one else has tried. The functions of total marketing include advertising, personal selling, packaging, pricing, channeling and warehousing. Borden also identified the market forces affecting marketing mix:
- Consumer buying behavior
- Trade’s behavior (wholesale and retailing)
- Competitors position and behavior: industry structure, product choice, oversupply, pricing and innovation
- Governmental behavior: regulations
Borden concludes saying that marketing is more an art than a science. The marketer E. Jerome McCarthy proposed a four Ps classification (product, price, promotion, place) in 1960, which has since been used by marketers throughout the world.[39] Koichi Shimizu proposed a 7Cs Compass Model (corporation, commodity, cost, communication, channel, consumer, circumstances) to provide a more complete picture of the nature of marketing in 1981. Robert F. Lauterborn wrote about the Four P’s in 1990[40]
When Jerry McCarthy and Phil Kotler proposed their alliterative litany — Product, Price, Place and Promotion — the marketing world was very different. Roaring out of World War II with a
cranked-up production system ready to feed a lust for better living, American business linked management science to the art of mass marketing and rocketed to the moon. In the days of «Father Knows Best,» it all seemed so simple. The advertiser developed a product, priced it to make a profit, placed it on the retail shelf and promoted it to a pliant, even eager consumer. Mass media simultaneously taught consumptive culture and provided advertisers with efficient access to an audience which would behave, Dr. Dichter assured us, perfectly predictably, given the proper stimulation.
He instead advocated a four Cs classification which is a more consumer-oriented version of the four Ps that attempts to better fit the movement from mass marketing to niche marketing:
- Consumer: don’t focus on product, study consumer wants and needs
- Cost: forget price, instead understand the consumer cost to satisfy that want or need, even driving time versus time spent with family matters
- Communication: forget promotion, instead focus on communication and create dialogue
- Convenience: forget place, instead think about convenience to buy, know each market subsegment
Sociology[edit]
Economic rationality[edit]
Max Weber defines the measure of rational economic action as the:[41]
- Systematic distribution of utilities between present and future
- Systematic distribution of utilities between various potential uses
- Systematic production of utilities by manufacture or transportation by the owner of the means of production
- Systematic acquisition by agreement of the powers of control and disposal over utilities, mainly by establishing corporate groups or by exchange
Opposition of interests is typically resolved by bargaining or by competitive biding:
- Utilities, goods and labour are at the disposal of the individual without interference from others
- Transportation can be seen as a part of the process of production
- It is indifferent whether the individual is prevented from using force to interfere in the controls of others by means of a legal order, convention, custom, self-interest or moral standards
- Competition for the means of production may exist under various conditions
- Anything which may be transferred between individuals by compensation may be an object of exchange
- Conditions of exchange may be traditional, conventional (exchange of gifts) or rational (motivated by profit or need)
- Regulations may threaten the source of supply
Money may classified as:
- Coined money is called «free money» or «market money» when it is coined by the mint without limit of amount
- It is called «limited» money or «administrative money» if the issue of coinage if subject to a corporate group
- It is called regulated money if the kind and amount of coinage is subject to rules
Weber defines:
- Market situation: all the opportunities of exchanging a good for money that are known by the participants
- Marketability: degree of regularity that a good tends to be an object of exchange in the market
- Market freedom: degree of autonomy enjoyed by the participants in price determination and competition
- Market regulation: restrictions on marketability and market freedom, done by tradition, convention, law, voluntary action
Trade networks are very old and in this picture the blue line shows the trade network of the Radhanites, circa 870 CE
Weber defines «formal rationality of economic action» to designate the extent of quantitative calculation or accounting and «substantive rationality» as the degree a group of persons is or could be adequately provided with good by means of oriented course of social action. A prominent entry-point for challenging the market model’s applicability concerns exchange transactions and the homo economicus assumption of self-interest maximization. As of 2012, a number of streams of economic sociological analysis of markets focus on the role of the social in transactions and on the ways transactions involve social networks and relations of trust, cooperation and other bonds.[42] Economic geographers in turn draw attention to the ways exchange transactions occur against the backdrop of institutional, social and geographic processes, including class relations, uneven development and historically contingent path-dependencies.[43] Pierre Bourdieu has suggested the market model is becoming self-realizing in virtue of its wide acceptance in national and international institutions through the 1990s.[44]
Abstraction, market agencement and framing[edit]
Michel Callon traces the history of how the market as a place (fairs, flea markets, fish markets) became an abstract concept (market for ideas, dating market, job market) which he calls the interface market model.[45] This abstraction proceeds in three layers:
- Sellers, buyers, platform goods
- Competition
- Institutions
The interface market model thus establishes that:
- Agents and goods are distinguable
- A transfer is a communication of property rights
- Competition develops between agents
- A transaction consists of monetary payments
The limitations of this model are:
- They do not take into account the material composition of market activities
- They bracket out the constructive process of creating supply and demand, which leads to underestimating the crucial role played by bilateral transactions and the initiation of these transactions
- They create unrealism through the concepts of aggregated supply and demand and bring about difficulties in comprehending the actual mechanisms for establishing prices
- They create a total impasse on the complex processes that result in a separation between agents and goods
- The hypothesis that goods are platforms precludes us from recognizing they are processes
- A description of agents that underestimates their diversity, heterogeneity, and plasticity
Callon offer the market agencements (heterogenous assemblage) model as an alternative, its features being:
- Competition is the struggle to establish bilateral transactions that are never identical
- Innovation is fundamental to commercial activity
- Goods are processes
- Profilerating agents, plastic identities and networking
Market agencements function through framing, that is action is oriented to a strategic goal (obtaining bilateral transactions), for example market oriented passiva(c)tion:
- Detaches the good and liberates it from all those who participated in its elaboration and profiling
- Renders it apt to provoke courses of actions and to contribute to their realization (that is, imbues it with uses)
- Ensures that its behavior is at least to a certain extent controllable and predictable
- Organizes the attribution and transfer of property rights
Callon identifies the activities necessary for framing:
- Rendering goods pass(act)ive
- Activating agencies capable of evaluating and transforming these goods
- Organizing their encounter
- Ensuring the attachment of the goods to the agencies
- Obtaining consent to pay
- Setting a price and compelling payment–actions that combine and interweave with one another, with possible feedback loops and iterations
Embeddedness[edit]
Alfred Marshall wrote:[19]
Thus it is on the one side a study of wealth; and on the other, and more important side, a part of the study of man. For man’s character has been moulded by his every-day work, and the material resources which he thereby procures, more than by any other influence unless it be that of his religious ideals; and the two great forming agencies of the world’s history have been the religious and the economic. Here and there the ardour of the military or the artistic spirit has been for a while predominant: but religious and economic influences have nowhere been displaced from the front rank even for a time; and they have nearly always been more important than all others put together. Religious motives are more intense than economic, but their direct action seldom extends over so large a part of life. For the business by which a person earns his livelihood generally fills his thoughts during by far the greater part of those hours in which his mind is at its best; during them his character is being formed by the way in which he uses his faculties in his work, by the thoughts and the feelings which it suggests, and by his relations to his associates in work, his employers or his employees.
According to Max Weber the spirit of capitalism as preached by Benjamin Franklin is directly connected with utilitarianism, rationalism and Protestantism. Luther calling was not a monastic one but involves the fulfilments of obligations imposed by one’s position in the world. The pursuit of money and earthly goods was not viewed positively by Protestantism, the Puritans however emphasized that God blessings, like in the Book of Job, applied also to material life. The limitation of consumption inevitably results in capital accumulation, therefore, for Weber, the Puritan’s idea of the calling and ascetic conduct contributed to development of capitalism: saving is an ascetic activity.[46]
Embeddedness expresses the idea that the economy is not autonomous but subordinated to politics, religion, and social relations. Polanyi’s use of the term suggests the now familiar idea that market transactions depend on trust, mutual understanding, and legal enforcement of contracts.[47] Michel Callon’s concept of framing provides a useful schema: each economic act or transaction occurs against, incorporates and also re-performs a geographically and cultural specific complex of social histories, institutional arrangements, rules and connections. These network relations are simultaneously bracketed, so that persons and transactions may be disentangled from thick social bonds. The character of calculability is imposed upon agents as they come to work in markets and are “formatted” as calculative agencies. Market exchanges contain a history of struggle and contestation that produced actors predisposed to exchange under certain sets of rules. Therefore, for Challon, market transactions can never be disembedded from social and geographic relations and there is no sense to talking of degrees of embeddedness and disembeddeness.[48] During the 20th century two common forms of critique were made:
- Categories of 19th century social science such as class, modernity or the West were social constructions
- These categories were artificial and not universal
These are common themes in interpretive social science, cultural studies and post-structuralism. However, as Timothy Mitchell points out this mode of thought tends to put aside the real, the natural and nonhuman: the idea that a universal processes exists such as modernity, capitalism and globalization should not be taken for granted.[49] An emerging theme is the interrelationship, inter-penetrability and variations of concepts of persons, commodities and modes of exchange under particular market formations. This is most pronounced in recent movement towards post-structuralist theorizing that draws on Michel Foucault and Actor Network Theory and stress relational aspects of person-hood, and dependence and integration into networks and practical systems. Commodity network approaches further both deconstruct and show alternatives to the market models concept of commodities.[50]
[edit]
In social systems theory (cf. Niklas Luhmann), markets are also conceptualized as inner environments of the economy. As horizon of all potential investment decisions the market represents the environment of the actually realized investment decisions. However, such inner environments can also be observed in further function systems of society like in political, scientific, religious or mass media systems.[51]
Economic geography[edit]
Wilhelm Launhardt, a location theorist, wrote:[52]
The conditions governing the distribution and settling of the population over any area are dependent on the nature of its economic activity: and when this activity is engaged in the cultivation of the surface of the ground and in the husbandry of land and wood and on many kinds of handicrafts and small manufactures this distribution is to be assumed as uniform over the area; although, as a matter of fact, the population usually lives collected together in small hamlets, and the number of the inhabitants per unit of area, or density of population, varies according to the local conditions. Another part of the population, namely that which is engaged in wholesale commerce, the various professions of Art and Science, and that which consists of merchants and officials, lives collected in towns.
Transportation can be carried either by stone-paved roads or railways, the former not being fully developed by private capital alone. A widespread trend in economic history and sociology is skeptical of the idea that it is possible to develop a theory to capture an essence or unifying thread to markets.[53] For economic geographers, reference to regional, local, or commodity specific markets can serve to undermine assumptions of global integration and highlight geographic variations in the structures, institutions, histories, path dependencies, forms of interaction and modes of self-understanding of agents in different spheres of market exchange.[54] Reference to actual markets can show capitalism not as a totalizing force or completely encompassing mode of economic activity, but rather as «a set of economic practices scattered over a landscape, rather than a systemic concentration of power».[55]
Problematic for market formalism is the relationship between formal capitalist economic processes and a variety of alternative forms, ranging from semi-feudal and peasant economies widely operative in many developing economies, to informal markets, barter systems, worker cooperatives, or illegal trades that occur in most developed countries. Practices of incorporation of non-Western peoples into global markets in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries did not merely result in the quashing of former social economic institutions. Rather, various modes of articulation arose between transformed and hybridized local traditions and social practices and the emergent world economy. By their liberal nature, so called capitalist markets have almost always included a wide range of geographically situated economic practices that do not follow the market model. Economies are thus hybrids of market and non-market elements.[56] Helpful here is J.K. Gibson-Graham’s complex topology of the diversity of contemporary market economies describing different types of transactions, labour and economic agents. Transactions can occur in black markets (such as for marijuana) or be artificially protected (such as for patents). They can cover the sale of public goods under privatization schemes to co-operative exchanges and occur under varying degrees of monopoly power and state regulation. Likewise, there are a wide variety of economic agents, which engage in different types of transactions on different terms: one cannot assume the practices of a religious kindergarten, multinational corporation, state enterprise, or community-based cooperative can be subsumed under the same logic of calculability. This emphasis on proliferation can also be contrasted with continuing scholarly attempts to show underlying cohesive and structural similarities to different markets.[42] Gibson-Graham thus read a variety of alternative markets for fair trade and organic foods or those using local exchange trading system as not only contributing to proliferation, but also forging new modes of ethical exchange and economic subjectivities.
Anthropology[edit]
Economic anthropology is a scholarly field that attempts to explain human economic behavior in its widest historic, geographic and cultural scope. Its origins as a sub-field of anthropology begin with the Polish-British founder of anthropology, Bronisław Malinowski, and his French compatriot, Marcel Mauss, on the nature of gift-giving exchange (or reciprocity) as an alternative to market exchange. Studies in economic anthropology for the most part are focused on exchange but they a complex relationship with the discipline of economics, of which it is highly critical:[57] for example Trobianders described by Malinowski deviate from rational self-interested individual.[58]
Bronisław Malinowski’s path-breaking work, Argonauts of the Western Pacific (1922), addressed the question «why would men risk life and limb to travel across huge expanses of dangerous ocean to give away what appear to be worthless trinkets?». He begins by describing trade in the South Sea:[58]
The coastal populations of the South Sea Islands, with very few exceptions, are, or were before their extinction, expert navigators and traders. Several of them had evolved excellent types of large sea-going canoes, and used to embark in them on distant trade expeditions or raids of war and conquest. The Papuo-Melanesians, who inhabit the coast and the outlying islands of New Guinea, are no exception to this rule. In general they are daring sailors, industrious manufacturers, and keen traders. The manufacturing centres of important articles, such as pottery, stone implements, canoes, fine baskets, valued ornaments, are localised in several places, according to the skill of the inhabitants, their inherited tribal tradition, and special facilities offered by the district; thence they are traded over wide areas, sometimes travelling more than hundreds of miles. Definite forms of exchange along definite trade routes are to be found established between the various tribes. A most remarkable form of intertribal trade is that obtaining between the Motu of Port Moresby and the tribes of the Papuan Gulf. The Motu sail for hundreds of miles in heavy, unwieldy canoes, called lakatoi, which are provided with the characteristic crab-claw sails. They bring pottery and shell ornaments, in olden days, stone blades, to Gulf Papuans, from whom they obtain in exchange sago and the heavy dug-outs, which are used afterwards by the Motu for the construction of their lakatoi canoes.
The economic situation can vary considerably depending on the tribes and islands: for example the Gumawana villagers are known as efficient sailors and for their skill in pottery, they are, however, island monopolists keeping the trade in their own hands without improving it. In a series of three expeditions, Malinowski carefully traced the network of exchanges of bracelets and necklaces across the Trobriand Islands and established that they were part of a system of inter-tribal exchange: it is known as the Kula ring, a closed circuit in which necklaces of red shells go in a clockwise motion and bracelets of white shell go in anticlockwise motion. Malinowski goes on to explain:[58]
Thus in the Introduction we called the Kula a “form of trade,” and we ranged it alongside other systems of barter. This is quite correct, if we give the word “trade” a sufficiently wide interpretation, and mean by it any exchange of goods. But the word “trade” is used in current Ethnography and economic literature with so many different implications that a whole lot of misleading, preconceived ideas have to be brushed aside in order to grasp the facts correctly. Thus the aprioric current notion of primitive trade would be that of an exchange of indispensable or useful articles, done without much ceremony or regulation, under stress of dearth or need, in spasmodic, irregular intervals—and this done either by direct barter, everyone looking out sharply not to be done out of his due, or, if the savages were too timid and distrustful to face one another, by some customary arrangement, securing by means of heavy penalties compliance in the obligations incurred or imposed.* Waiving for the present the question how far this conception is valid or not in general—in my opinion it is quite misleading—we have to realise clearly that the Kula contradicts in almost every point the above definition of “savage trade.” It shows to us primitive exchange in an entirely different light.
The Kula is not a surreptitious and precarious form of exchange. It is, quite on the contrary, rooted in myth, backed by traditional law, and surrounded with magical rites. All its main transactions are public and ceremonial, and carried out according to definite rules. It is not done on the spur of the moment, but happens periodically, at dates settled in advance, and it is carried on along definite trade routes, which must lead to fixed trysting places. Sociologically, though transacted between tribes differing in language, culture, and probably even in race, it is based on a fixed and permanent status, on a partnership which binds into couples some thousands of individuals. This partnership is a lifelong relationship, it implies various mutual duties and privileges, and constitutes a type of inter-tribal relationship on an enormous scale. As to the economic mechanism of the transactions, this is based on a specific form of credit, which implies a high degree of mutual trust and commercial honour—and this refers also to the subsidiary, minor trade, which accompanies the Kula proper. Finally, the Kula is not done under stress of any need, since its main aim is to exchange articles which are of no practical use.
French crown jewels in the Louvre exhibition
In the 1920s and later, Malinowski’s study became the subject of debate with the French anthropologist, Marcel Mauss, author of The Gift (Essai sur le don, 1925).[59] Malinowski emphasized the exchange of goods between individuals and their non-altruistic motives for giving: they expected a return of equal or greater value (colloquially referred to as «Indian giving»). In other words, reciprocity is an implicit part of gifting as no «free gift» is given without expectation of reciprocity. In contrast, Mauss has emphasized that the gifts were not between individuals, but between representatives of larger collectivities.
He stated that this exchange system was clearly linked to political authority.[60] He argued these gifts were a «total prestation» as they were not simple, alienable commodities to be bought and sold, but like the «Crown jewels» embodied the reputation, history and sense of identity of a «corporate kin group», such as a line of kings. Given the stakes, Mauss asked «why anyone would give them away?» and his answer was an enigmatic concept, «the spirit of the gift». A good part of the confusion (and resulting debate) was due to a bad translation. Mauss appeared to be arguing that a return gift is given to keep the very relationship between givers alive; a failure to return a gift ends the relationship; and the promise of any future gifts. Based on an improved translate, Jonathan Parry has demonstrated that Mauss was arguing that the concept of a «pure gift» given altruistically only emerges in societies with a well-developed market ideology.[60]
Rather than emphasize how particular kinds of objects are either gifts or commodities to be traded in restricted spheres of exchange, Arjun Appadurai and others began to look at how objects flowed between these spheres of exchange. They shifted attention away from the character of the human relationships formed through exchange and placed it on «the social life of things» instead. They examined the strategies by which an object could be «singularized» (made unique, special, one-of-a-kind) and so withdrawn from the market. A marriage ceremony that transforms a purchased ring into an irreplaceable family heirloom is one example whereas the heirloom, in turn, makes a perfect gift.
Mathematical modeling[edit]
Although arithmetic has been used since the beginning of civilization to set prices, it was not until the 19th century that data was systematically collected and more advanced mathematical tools began to be used to study markets in the form of social statistics. Business intelligence is also dated to the 19th century, but it was with the rise of the computer that business analytics exploded. More recent techniques involve data mining and marketing engineering.
Size parameters[edit]
Market size can be given in terms of the number of buyers and sellers in a particular market[61] or in terms of the total exchange of money in the market, generally annually (per year). When given in terms of money, market size is often termed «market value», but in a sense distinct from market value of individual products. For one and the same goods, there may be different (and generally increasing) market values at the production level, the wholesale level and the retail level. For example, the value of the global illicit drug market for the year 2003 was estimated by the United Nations to be US$13 billion at the production level, $94 billion at the wholesale level (taking seizures into account) and US$322 billion at the retail level (based on retail prices and taking seizures and other losses into account).[62]
-
United States home sales (blue)
-
Book Sales in the United Kingdom
-
See also[edit]
- Grocery store
- Justice and the Market
- Knowledge market
- Market economy
- Market engineering
- Market information systems
- Market microstructure
- Market town
- Shopper marketing
References[edit]
- ^ «Transaction», Oxford Dictionaries. Retrieved 25 October 2014.
- ^ a b c Coase, Ronald (1937). «The Nature of the Firm». Economica. Blackwell Publishing. 4 (16): 386–405. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x. JSTOR 2626876.
- ^ Williamson, Oliver E. (1989). «3: Transaction Cost Economies». Handbook of Industrial Organization. Vol. 1. Elsevier. pp. 135–182. doi:10.1016/S1573-448X(89)01006-X. ISBN 9780444704344.
- ^ Grossman, Sanford J.; Hart, Oliver D. (1986). «The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration». Journal of Political Economy. 94 (4): 691–719. doi:10.1086/261404.
- ^ Kállay, Balázs (2012). «Contract Theory of the Firm». Journal of Scientific Papers ECONOMICS & SOCIOLOGY. 5: 39–50. doi:10.14254/2071-789X.2012/5-1/3.
- ^ Lafontaine, Francine; Slade, Margaret (2007). «Vertical Integration and Firm Boundaries: The Evidence» (PDF). Journal of Economic Literature. 45 (3): 629–685. doi:10.1257/jel.45.3.629. JSTOR 27646842.
- ^ «80% of trade takes place in ‘value chains’ linked to transnational corporations, UNCTAD report says». United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 27 February 2013. Retrieved 18 July 2020.
- ^ «World Investment Report 1996». United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 1996. Retrieved 18 July 2020.
- ^ Antras, Pol (2015). «Global Production: Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure» (PDF). Retrieved 19 July 2020.
- ^ Rajan, Raghuram G.; Zingales, Luigi (1998). «Financial Dependence and Growth». The American Economic Review. 88 (3): 559–586. doi:10.3386/w5758. JSTOR 116849.
- ^
Heyne, Paul; Boettke, Peter J.; Prychitko, David L. (2014). The Economic Way of Thinking (13th ed.). Pearson. pp. 130–132. ISBN 978-0-13-299129-2. - ^ O’Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Pearson Prentice Hall. p. 28. ISBN 978-0-13-063085-8.
- ^ Robert S. Pindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Microeconomics, Pearson International Edition 2009
- ^ Diaz Ruiz, C.A. (2012). «Theories of markets: Insights from marketing and the sociology of markets». The Marketing Review. 12 (1): 61–77. doi:10.1362/146934712X13286274424316.
- ^ Callon, M. (1998) «Introduction: The Embeddedness of Economic Markets in Economics.» In The Laws of the Markets, edited by Michel Callon. Basic Blackwell/The Sociological Review pp. 1–57 1998, p.2).
- ^ A. Smith, The Wealth of Nations, 1776, Book IV, Of systems of political economy
- ^ A. Smith, The Wealth of Nations, 1776, Book I, Chapter II, Of the principle which gives occasion to the division of labour
- ^ A. Smith, The Wealth of Nations, 1776, Book I, Chapter V, Of the real and nominal price of commodities, or of their price in labour, and their price of money
- ^ a b A. Marshall, Principles of Economics, 1890
- ^ A. Cournot, Researches into the mathematical principles of the theory of wealth, 1838 https://archive.org/details/researchesintom00fishgoog
- ^ Chamberlin, E.H. (1937). «Monopolistic or Imperfect Competition?». Quarterly Journal of Economics. 51 (4): 557–580. doi:10.2307/1881679. JSTOR 1881679.
- ^ Hotteling, H. (1929). «Stability in Competition». The Economic Journal. 39 (153): 41–57. doi:10.2307/2224214. JSTOR 2224214.
- ^ Baumol, William J. (1977). «On the Proper Cost Tests for Natural Monopoly in a Multiproduct Industry». American Economic Review. 67 (5): 809–822. JSTOR 1828065.
- ^ Baumol W., Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Industry Structure, American Economic Review vol 72 pp. 1-15 1982 http://econ.ucdenver.edu/beckman/research/readings/baumol-contestable.pdf
- ^ Akerlof, George A. (1970). «The Market for ‘Lemons’: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism». Quarterly Journal of Economics. 84 (3): 488–500. doi:10.2307/1879431. JSTOR 1879431.
- ^ Spence, A. M. (1973). «Job Market Signaling». Quarterly Journal of Economics. 87 (3): 355–374. doi:10.2307/1882010. JSTOR 1882010.
- ^ Greenwald, Bruce; Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1986). «Externalities in Economies with Imperfect Information and Incomplete Markets». Quarterly Journal of Economics. 101 (2): 229–264. doi:10.2307/1891114. JSTOR 1891114.
- ^ a b Lukács, György. (1971) History and Class Consciousness, Reification and the Consciousness of the Proletariat-I:The Phenomenon of Reification, Trans. Rodney Livingstone. Merlin Press. London.
- ^ Lukács, György. (1971) History and Class Consciousness. Trans. Rodney Livingstone. Merlin Press. London. p. 87
- ^ MacPherson, C.B. (1962) The Political Theory of Possessive Individualism: From Hobbes to Locke. Oxford Clarendon Press. p.3
- ^ Swedberg, 1994, p. 258
- ^ Harvey, David (2005) A Short History of Neoliberalism Oxford University Press.
- ^ Peck, supra, p. 154)
- ^ Bakker, Karen (2005) «Neoliberalizing Nature?: Market Environmentalism in water supply in England and Wales» Annals of the Association of American Geographers 95 (3), 542–565
- ^ Converse, Paul Dulaney and Jones, Fred M. (1948). Introduction to Marketing — Principles of Wholesale and Retail Distribution. Prentice-Hall
- ^ Michael J Baker, Michael John Baker, Michael Saren, Marketing Theory: A Student Text, SAGE 2010
- ^
Borden, Neil. «The Concept of the Marketing Mix». Suman Thapa. Retrieved 24 April 2013. - ^ Borden, Neil H. (1965). «The Concept of the Marketing Mix». In Schwartz, George (ed.). Science in marketing. Wiley marketing series. Wiley. pp. 286ff. ISBN 9780471766001. Retrieved November 4, 2013.
- ^ Needham, Dave (1996). Business for Higher Awards. Oxford, England: Heinemann.
- ^ Lauterborn, B. (1990). New Marketing Litany: Four Ps Passé: C-Words Take Over. Advertising Age, 61(41), 26.
- ^ Weber, Max. The Theory Of Social And Economic Organization. Free Press.
- ^ a b Swedberg, 1994, p. 267
- ^ Martin, Ron (2000) «Institutional Approaches in Economic Geography», Handbook of Economic Geography. Ed. Eric Sheppard and Trevor J. Barnes. Blackwell Publishers.Peck, 2005
- ^ Bourdieu, Pierre (1999) Acts of Resistance: Against the Tyranny of the Market. The New Press.p. 95
- ^
Callon, Michel (2021). Markets in the Making . Zone Books. - ^ Weber, Max (2012). The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, Start Publishing LLC.
- ^ Polanyi, Karl (2001). The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time. Beacon Press.
- ^ Callon, 1998; Mitchell, 2002, p. 291,
- ^ Timothy Mitchell. Rule of Experts: Egypt, Techno-Politics, Modernity
- ^ Hughes, Alex (2005) «Geographies of Exchange and Circulation: alternative trading spaces» Progress in Human Geography
- ^ Roth, Steffen (2012). «Leaving commonplaces on the common place: Cornerstones of a polyphonic market theory». Journal for Critical Organization Inquiry. 10 (3): 43–52. SSRN 2192754.
- ^ Launhardt Wilhelm 1900. The theory of trace: being a discussion of the principles of location, Lawrence Asylum Press
- ^
Swedberg, Richard (1994) «Markets as Social Structures» The Handbook of Economic Sociology. Ed. Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg. Princeton University Press. OCLC 29703776, p. 258) - ^
Peck, J. (2005) «Economic Geographies in Space» Economic Geography 81(2) 129–175. - ^ (Gibson-Graham, J.K. (2006) Postcapitalist Politics. University of Minnesota Press,. p. 2).
- ^ (Mitchell, Timothy (2002) Rule of Experts. University of California Pressp. 270; Gibson-Graham 2006, supra pp. 53–78)
- ^ Bourdieu, Pierre (2017). Anthropologie économique — Cours au Collège de France 1992-1993. Editions du Seuil.
- ^ a b c Malinowski, Bronislaw. Argonauts Of The Western Pacific — An Account of Native Enterprise and Adventure in the Archipelagoes of Melanesian New Guinea — Read Books Ltd.
- ^ Mauss, Marcel (1970). The Gift: Forms and Functions of Exchange in Archaic Societies. London: Cohen & West.
- ^ a b Parry, Jonathan (1986). «The Gift, the Indian Gift and the ‘Indian Gift’«. Man. 21 (3): 453–473. doi:10.2307/2803096. JSTOR 2803096. S2CID 152071807.
- ^ investorwords.com > market size Retrieved on April 17, 2010
- ^ United Nations, «2005 World Drug Report,» Office on Drugs and Crime, June 2005, p. 16. [1]
Further reading[edit]
Wikiquote has quotations related to Market.
- Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Microeconomics, Prentice Hall 2012.
- Frank, Robert H., Microeconomics and Behavior, 6th ed., McGraw-Hill/Irwin 2006.
- Kotler, P. and Keller, K.L., Marketing Management, Prentice Hall 2011.
- Baker, Michael J. and Michael Saren, Marketing Theory: A Student Text, Sage 2010. online.
- Aspers, Patrik, Markets, Polity Press 2011. online.
- Bauer, Leonard and Herbert Matis (1988) From moral to political economy: The Genesis of social sciences, History of European Ideas 9 (2), 125–143.
- Nathaus, Klaus and David Gilgen (Eds.), Change of Markets and Market Societies: Concepts and Case Studies. Historical Social Research 36 (3), Special Issue, 2011.
A market is any place where makers, distributors or retailers sell, and consumers buy. Examples include shops, high streets, or websites. The term may also refer to the whole group of buyers for a good or service.
Businesses that operate in markets are usually in competition with other companies. The other companies or rivals offer similar goods or services.
When the press writes about markets plummeting or going through the roof, they are usually referring to the price of shares (stocks), commodities or other derivatives. For example, the headline “US markets suffer biggest one-day loss in almost four years,” refers to Wall Street (Dow Jones Index), the S&P 500 and Nasdaq.
The United States is the world’s largest marketplace for most products and services. However, China is starting to take the number one spot in a number of sectors.
The term emerged in the British Isles in the early 1200s, and meant ‘a meeting at a fixed time for buying and selling livestock and provisions.’ It came from Old French ‘marchiet’, which meant ‘trade, commerce, marketplace.’ In most of Western Europe, the word can be traced back to the Latin ‘mercatus’, which meant ‘trading, marketplace, buying and selling.’
We often use the word ‘marketplace’ with the same meaning as ‘market.’ However, often ‘marketplace’ has a different meaning.
The Cambridge Dictionaries Online have the following definition of the term:
“The people who might want to buy something, or a part of the world where something is sold,” or “The business or trade in a particular product, including financial products.”
NetMBA says that the term market (in marketing) refers to a group of consumers or organizations that is interested in purchasing a product or service, has the resources to buy it, and is allowed to by law and other regulations to acquire it.
Markets are always changing – they are dynamic. Successful businesses are the ones that closely monitor trends and evolving consumer requirements, which are influenced by several factors, including changing economic conditions, lifestyles, new technologies, discoveries, or new fashions.
The prices of goods and services are established by the market. They facilitate trade and enable the distribution and allocation of resources within an economy. They allow any item or service that can be bought or sold to be evaluated and priced.
Markets either emerge naturally, spontaneously, or we build them deliberately.
The word may also refer to all the players within a sector. For example, the financial market means commercial banks, retail banks, pension funds, insurance companies – any environment where buyers and sellers trade in derivatives, bonds, equities and currencies.
Markets can be physical places
The term may refer to a physical place built to trade in specific goods, such as fish markets, farmers’ markets, street markets, food retail markets, and wet markets (sell meat and groceries).
Flea markets, for example, exist outdoors with stalls that sell second hand items, antiques, refurbished items, etc.
Any retail outlet, ranging from a tiny corner shop to a giant store is a type of market. Shopping malls, bazaars, souks, flea markets, and discount stores are markets.
Companies must define their market
One of the fundamental keys to business success is to first define your market – something many companies fail to do.
Experts say that a surprising number of businesses put together a marketing plan hastily. In other words, they do so without first defining exactly what their market is.
It is a bit like the person who is putting together a jig-saw puzzle in a hurry. Perhaps they do not first checking the picture on the back of the box. They may think they are assembling the pieces of the Eiffel Tower, but it is the Empire State Building.
Before deciding how you are going to get to those potential customers, you must be able to first define that market.
The economies of the US, Canada, Western Europe, Australasia and Japan are known as ‘open markets’. They contrast with the closed markets of Cuba and North Korea.
Quotes using the word ‘market’
Co-founder of Microsoft, multi-billionaire business magnate Bill Gates, said:
“If African farmers can use improved seeds and better practices to grow more crops and get them to market, then millions of families can earn themselves a better living and a better life.”
John F. Kennedy (1917-1963), the 35th President of the United States, said:
“A nation that is afraid to let its people judge the truth and falsehood in an open market is a nation that is afraid of its people.”
Billionaire business magnate, Warren Buffett, considered by many as the most successful investor of the twentieth century, said:
“Only buy something that you’d be perfectly happy to hold if the market shut down for 10 years.”
Market failure
This occurs when the market does not function as efficiently as it should. This could be because of:
- Externatilities, e.g. a factory contaminates the drinking water of nearby residents.
- The abuse of market power, e.g. monopolistic behaviors.
- A situation in which one person in a business deal has more information than the other person. We call this ‘asymmetric information.’
- When public goods, such as roads, railroads, national defense have to be provided by the state.
Video – Market definition
Someone gave me a little rice once, and I travelled two days to a market and traded it for some soap, and then travelled to another market and traded the soap for some beans. ❋ Unknown (2010)
Propalms plans to generate over $1 Million in revenue through the global sales of its new VPN 3.5, which will help the Company gain significant market share in the $5.8 Billion virtual applications +market. ❋ Unknown (2010)
«I wanted £320,000 but was persuaded by the agent to market at a more attractive price to drive significant amounts of interest,» says Paul Patton, whose three-bedroom home in Chorlton, Manchester, has just gone on the market for £295,000. ❋ Rupert Jones Graham Norwood (2009)
Immediately round Tamworth» a confiderable market town, and the ibil peculiarly rich, it lets for three to foui* pounds, ah acre* This, however, is iA ibme meafure accounted for, in the quantity of garden ground pultivated, here, for the Binningham market*. ❋ William (1796)
But Balcerowicz preferred the term market revolution. ❋ DANIEL YERGIN (1998)
Combined with PET23 liner, Global MDO offers the label market a differentiated film in the high-volume Home and Personal Care HPC market.
If the main market is the police officers in themselves why is this the first featured item in an online store which purports to be aimed at the general public? ❋ Unknown (2009)
The rare coin market is officially in a correction. ❋ Unknown (2009)
Another enticing market is the Medellin market in the Colonia Roma on Campeche between Medellin and Monterrey. ❋ Unknown (2006)
If the term market simply describes a situation where all economic relations are truly voluntary, than how is it incompatible with someone producing something with a view towards simply satisfying the needs of others? ❋ Unknown (2008)
De-coupling the education market from the housing market is a different issue (and I’ll happily admit that it is an issue the Lib Dems have failed to tackle adequately) that doesn’t neccessarily require «marketisation» to solve. ❋ Unknown (2005)
The main market is many square blocks and full of crafts and artisan work from the entire Mayan region including many vendors from the highland Maya in Chiapas and Guatemala. ❋ Unknown (2004)
«[Let’s get] that bread,» George said as he took his first [steps] into the [crowded] market. ❋ Robert Leonard (2019)
[Blimey], [I bet] she has a [lovely] market! ❋ Kevin Robinson (2006)
[See] Above for [the example] ❋ Murray State (2004)
see above for example. Be [wary] of any person who says they are «[Marketing]». Lose all hope when dealing with a «Marketing [Consultant]». ❋ Newmediamonkey (2007)
Bob “I ran into [Dwain] Dibbley the other day.”
Mike “Really, so what’s he up to these days?”
Bob “Apparently he’s a Marketeer for [MegaGlobal] Corp.”
Mike “Well; he always was an [unimaginative], spreadsheet licking twat!“
Bob “For sure.” ❋ Vince Mode (2017)
([XYZ] printer): Prints at 80 pages per minute! (The [fine print]: 80 pages per minute is achieved by placing one letter [‘A’] at 12 pitch type, in the middle of the page)
In marketing, there is no such thing as a ‘lie’, only exaggerations! ❋ Quisinart (2006)
Me: Bro, that chick I took home from [the bar] last night is [hella] [marketable].
Bro: Word! ❋ TBAG Pipe Fag. (2013)
Hey [baby] [I’m on] [the market] ❋ 69-pussy-killer-69 (2016)
Anyone wearing a [pink shirt] [on a regular] basis and working in [Hammersmith]. ❋ Noddy (2003)
Although [the market] was particularly [crowded], she pushed forward through crowds of people, knowing that she had to [get that bread].d ❋ Robert Leonard (2019)